Rivadavia's Idea Sprouts Forth In Australia
C. Villalobos Dominguez
[Reprinted from Land and Freedom, July-August
1927. Translated from Mundo Argentina, Buenos Aires]
Canberra: A city where all will be able to live and work without
being overloaded with the heavy burden of taxes and all will be able
to have a house of their own without having to buy the land.
IN this month of May, which is consecrated to the memory of the birth
of the Argentine nation, the most positive tribute for the
perpetuation of one of its most outstanding creators has been
provided, not by Argentines, but by men of another country and another
race; to be exact, by our antipodeans, in the Australian continent.
There, not with flattering words, but with enduring deeds, on the 9th
of May was inaugurated the Federal Parliament Building and in the act
celebrated the founding of a great city, which will be the capital of
a great democratic nation like our own, but showing itself to be more
capable, as we shall see, of real and transcendental progress.
The Australian nation, formed of autonomous states, was constituted
in the year 1901, and thus arose the necessity of giving to it a
national capital as seat of the federal government. It was considered
advisable to found a new city, just as was done here in the case of
the city of La Plata, in order to provide a capital for the province
of Buenos Aires.
On studying the best way of organizing the economic bases for the new
metropolis, the Australian authorities, in harmony with advanced
science and enlightened patriotism, decided to establish, as regards
the ground upon which it was to stand, a system of leasing which turns
out to be similar if not exactly the same as the system which was
conceived and implanted with success in our own country by our great
Argentine patriot, Bernardino Rivadavia.
The incipient civic culture of our country in those first days of its
national life was unable to appreciate sufficiently the extraordinary
gift that was bestowed upon it. It could not resist the reactionary
movement under Rosas, the tyrant, which annulled or postponed this and
so many other advanced reforms.
But a great and true thought never dies. Soon or late, it revives.
And it is with reflective emotion that we must observe the marvelous
fact that, on the other side of the globe and a century removed in
time, there arises in full vigor the same ideas which Rivadavia and
his friends fervently upheld as the guarantee of the future greatness
and happiness of the Argentine people.
Rivadavia's idea consisted, briefly, in affirming the principle that
the land of the country must not be sold to anyone, foreigner or
native; that said land must remain the common property of all men who
at any given time live there. It also established that each man can
use in any way any portion he may need in order to till it and occupy
it with his dwelling, factory or business, the only condition being
that of paying into the common treasury the economic rent attaching to
the portion he occupies.
This fundamental idea and principle, inculcated in the teachings of
the learned French physiocrats and the illustrious ministers of
Charles II, Campomanes and Floridablanca, was completed by the
enlightened intuition of Bernardino Rivadavia and shaped into a
practical procedure for carrying it out, utilizing the advantageous
position presented by the Republic, as a new country where at that
time almost all of the land was public property, not having been sold,
save to a very small extent, to private individuals.
By a special law decreed in 1826, the ancient Roman system of "enfiteusis"
was adopted, but improved by an innovation as admirable as it was
fundamental and fruitful. Instead of handing over the land to private
individuals for a long and indefinite period and at a fixed rate or
rental, it was conveyed to him at a variable rental. That is to say,
for a term equally long and undefined, but subject to revaluation
every ten years, after the first twenty years.
In this way the State accompanied step by step the natural course of
rising values and in the name of the common interest, collected for
the community the increased rental values which are the fruit, not of
the effort of the individual, but of the general progress and
activities of the community.
The ideal of Rivadavia may in concrete be described as creating a
nation in which all citizens would be equally landlords, a nation in
which there would be no taxes (since the rent of the common land would
more than suffice for the public expenses), a nation, finally, in
which all the inhabitants would be rich, since the abovementioned
economic bases would make easy for all the access to the land (which
is the primary, inevitable and constant basis of all industrial
processes), and also make easy production and consumption, with all
due respect for the private ownership by each individual of goods
produced by himself.
That accurately conceived plan, which was so lament ably defeated, is
what has just been revived, even though only locally, in the new city
of Canberra. There the ground is not sold to anybody; it is given in
lease for ninety nine years, on a rental or rate fixed by public
auction, said rental or rate being valid for twenty years, renewable
every ten years after on a new valuation. Upon this economic basis,
which has already been tested tentatively in the neighboring city of
Adelaide and in many other Australian and New Zealand communities,
there is no doubt that the new capital will develop extraordinarily,
along the lines of the admirable plan prepared by the architect, Mr.
Walter Burley Griffin, who incidentally is an old disciple of Henry
George.
The analogy between the economic system implanted in Canberra and
that of Rivadavia is complete, with the exception of minor executive
details.
The genesis of this innovation did not arise in Australia from the
direct study of Rivadavia's plan (although that is familiar to
Georgists all over the world), but rather to the campaign which the
great North American economist, Henry George, carried on there about
the year 1880. (Incidentally it may be stated that, at that very time,
the Uruguayan, Dr. Andres Lamas, was composing in Buenos Aires his
splendid work upon the Agrarian Law of Rivaavia.)
Nevertheless, in the profound teachings of Henry George there is no
trace of plagiarism, as might be supposed. On the contrary, the
doctrines of George sprang spontaneously from his intelligence, in the
natural evolution of his own observations and reasoning, without any
acquaintance with the Rivadavian precedents. Others also, in other
countries, have arrived close to the same solution. And this is
comprehensible; because, when related facts are found incarnate in
reality, it is not astonishing that several thinkers should discover
and formulate them in scientific laws or practical measures of action.
As Henry George once said, it is not impossible that, from widely
different observation points, two men looking at the sky should
discover the same star.
Looking upon the soil of his country, and filled with an intense
desire to discover its secret possibilities for the luxuriant growth
of the human flora, Rivadavia and then George saw the truth. The
former established a plan for preserving the common property where it
already existed; the latter, to restore it to common property when, as
with us it happens, the ignorance and carelessness of past govern
ments committed the frightful folly of alienating it.
Other men with good intentions have tried to remedy the grave evils
of social injustice under the inspiration of false European doctrines,
without realizing that here in America they had at hand a solution
that was higher and truer. As Lamas well understood (and experience
has confirmed his opinion) the modern pseudoscience of political
economy in Europe, whether posing as conservative or advanced, cannot
be accepted as a proper and safe guide.
Down through the years the message of those great men reaches us,
preserved and disseminated by the prodigious invention of the printing
press. The greatest mission of the present generation is to bring it
to pass. And the example of Canberra, a decisive experiment of
worldwide importance, is a call to study and to action on the part of
all men of heart and intellect, since our glorious constitution and
the providential Law of Saenz Pena place within the hands of the
people the possibility of bringing it to pass, with ease, in order and
in peace.
What the people have first to learn is to hold as treason to the
nation the sale to private persons of another inch of Argentine land
still remaining public property.
|