City Planning and Taxes
Abraham J. Falick
[Reprinted from California Homeowner, June,
1968]
The impact of taxation and fiscal policies in general upon urban
growth structure is sometimes overlooked in the generation of city
plans. Failure to account for these taxation effects can result in
development of urban patterns in unintended and disadvantageous ways.
In our private enterprise economy we depend upon a market price
system to stimulate production of goods and services by its direct
reflection of consumer demand via prices that the buyers pay. The "goods
and services" provided by the various levels of government seldom
have the benefit of such direct interest in its product since its "marketplace
demand" relies mainly upon the political process and the
judgments of departmental administrators - including tax appraisers
and city planners.
Legislators and administrators influence industrial activity and
housing sites, the market for both public and private products (such
as land or buildings) with control levers of taxation and
expenditures. Policies viewed as economic abstractions and cash flows
are translated into the geographical facts of location and
distribution of commercial/industrial activity and housing sites. The
city planning problem with respect to taxes gets entangled with these
politico-economic issues:
(1) the search for easily-collected taxes by legislators and
administrators,
(2) the short-run viewpoint of some taxpayers,
(3) municipal jurisdictional boundaries.
ASSESSORS TEND TO IGNORE HIGHEST AND BEST USE OF LAND
An easily-collected tax is not always the "fairest" in
terms of ability-to-pay. With respect to property taxes this has
usually meant the appraisers, for example, will prefer to set taxes "objectively"
on the value of land and improvements as they now stand. They look
upon "subjective" taxation on the basis of earning power or
potential highest-and-best-use as a basket of snakes. This method
requires some Solomon-like distinctions with respect to commercial and
residential use as well as with current and future zoning practices.
While the complexity of the latter approach, with main emphasis on
the intrinsic land values, can be appreciated it is still believed by
many economists (including the writer) to be a more effective way of
using market processes to gradually eliminate central city slums. Such
a tax approach would also permit a more rational functioning of
economic activity in the core area. Land-value taxation is more likely
to reflect the potential earning power of a property which is
attributable to its location; it removes the tax penalty on
improvements. Pittsburgh presently taxes land at full value while
improvements are taxed at half value to encourage new construction.
The present "easy" and "objective" (abnormally
low) tax has a perverse effect upon urban planning by keeping slum
property or vacant land prices artificially high perpetuating the
downhill slide of the central city, and shifting its legitimate share
of taxation to other parts of the city. A higher tax on these
well-located lands would permit their prices to decline to normal
levels and encourage highest-and-best-use as determined in the market
place. As a recent article in Harper's Magazine, May 1968, on the
effect of the present tax approach points:
"Land speculators deliberately keep land idle
because of the low taxes. The homeowner, along with apartment and
commercial property owners, pays higher taxes on his improved land,
in effect subsidizing the land speculators who simply wait for the
entire community to push up the price of their land."
A PUBLIC EXPENDITURE SHOULD BECOME AN ASSET NOT AN EXPENSE
The short-run viewpoint of some taxpayers stems in part from the
failure to treat public expenditures on the same basis as business
expenditures. When a corporation invests in "machinery or
buildings one assumes, correctly, that the purpose is to make its
operations more productive, more profitable. The investment is listed
as an asset on the balance sheet and becomes a part of the
stockholders equity. Unfortunately, when city growth and improvement
call for similar public investment in schools, fire/police protection,
rapid transit, and urban renewal the short-runners view these as "expenses"
rather than as basic assets in the community infrastructure.
Bond issue defeats and failure to provide tax revenues are a result
of this point of view and makes rational planning for future needs
difficult or impossible. The effect of such neglect is that the
community declines in its functional and economic efficiency, in time
it becomes a less desirable place in which to live. Part of the
attractiveness of California is the fact that it has kept up most of
its public investments - particularly in educational and highway
planning - unlike many eastern cities. A time of testing for attitudes
toward transportation planning and public expenditure will come in
November when voters decide the proposed rapid transit system which
will provide a vital balance to the transport needs of the Los Angeles
area. Stanford Research Institute, viewing the 89 mile network as
strictly an investment, calculated a $1.87 return to the community for
each dollar put up.
SPRAWL CONTRIBUTES TO HIGHER COSTS FOR SERVICES
The City of Los Angeles with its 463 sq. mi. area is one of the
largest town plots in the nation but its tax base and planning efforts
suffer from irregular boundaries and framented jurisdictions. Its
territory completely or partially surrounds six of its suburbs with
overlapping and crossing service areas; the planning problems can be
imagined. Perhaps more serious in its effect on the tax base and city
planning are the so-called Phantom Cities or "dropout-towns"
of Los Angeles County which are industrial, strip-commercial, or
high-income residential enclaves which exist mainly to escape ordinary
municipal taxes.
These industrial/commercial "cities" have no health/welfare
problems, and require minimal fire and police protection. Los Angeles
and other towns provide these services for their workers. The
high-income residential enclaves also insulate themselves from urban
problems - but depend mainly upon the City of Los Angeles for their
livelihood and major cultural amenities.
The presence of cut-rate tax haven "cities" handicaps urban
planning by draining the industrial base and the high-income citizens
from the city proper. The larger city and its residents have less
funds for operations, planning, and community investment while the "phantoms"
enjoy a tax windfall.
A JUST PROPERTY TAX CAN BE AN AID TO PLANNING
In short, taxes and planning are intimately related; Los Angeles and
many other cities are trying to develop tax programs which will permit
more logical planning and better implementation of these plans for the
future. Councilman Edmund Edelman, chairman of the Revenue and
Taxation Committee of the Los Angeles City Council has enlisted the
aid of a team of UCLS fiscal economists to prepare new tax approaches
for the city. To resolve at least some of the geo-economic and
planning problems cited above the UCLA group and the committee will
examine tax incentives for desirable intensities of use, penalties for
undesirable ones, user-benefit charges and other proposals.
Tax effects on planning take place whether intended or not, with
increasing awareness of the fiscal impact on planning -- and the
planning effects on taxation - one can make more rational choices
about the structure of the community in which we live. We may not like
taxes but no civilization exists without them; let us use taxes as
part of the apparatus to plan a better future.
|