A Dialogue With Socialists on the Single Tax
Joseph Fels, et al.*
[What follows is a running exchange on The Single Tax
between Joseph Fels, the editors and various socialist correspondents,
reprinted from issues of the London-based Socialist publication, The
New Age, from 1908 thru 1918]
The Single Tax and Socialism
H. Chomley and Joseph Fels / 17 December 1908, p.162.
Is there any good and sufficient reason why single taxers and
Socialists should not work shoulder to shoulder in close alliance for
that amelioration of social conditions -for that radical change in the
basis of society which both feel is essential if this world is to
become a fit place for the vast majority of its people to live in?
Differ as they may concerning some of the means by which this
bettering of conditions is to be accomplished, they agree as to
others, and their ultimate aim is practically identical: namely, to
make the mass of the people full participants in the vast wealth and
the immense store of material advantages which the industrial forces
of the world, rightly used, might produce.
It is true that the Socialist -- or so we understand the mailer --
regards the nationalisation of all means of production, distribution
and exchange, as the only way towards the adequate socialisation of
wealth, while the single taxer believes that such socialisation can be
brought about by nationalising, through taxation, the land, and those
things which arc in (heir nature monopolies. But this difference ought
to count for little in the face of the wrongs and abuses which
Socialists and single taxers agree should be attacked here and now.
Two men who are travelling the same road, whereon enemies must be
fought before progress can be made, would be foolish in refusing to
join forces because one of them, after miles of the journey had been
accomplished, intended to take a turning which the other believed
would not lead to the objective which both had ultimately in view.
Such travellers are the single taxer and the Socialist, and surely
they should combine to fight their way along the first stages of their
perilous economic journey.
In proof of our contention that their ultimate aim is practically
indistinguishable, let us quote a portion of the passage from
Progress and Poverty, in which Henry George points to the
changes he desires to accomplish, and believes would result from the
single tax :
"There would be a great and increasing surplus
revenue from the taxation of land values, for material progress,
which would go on with greatly accelerated rapidity, would tend
constantly to increase rent. This revenue arising from the common
property could be applied to the common benefit, as were the
revenues of Sparta. We might not establish public tables - they
would be unnecessary; but we could establish public baths, museums,
libraries, gardens, lecture rooms, music and dancing halls,
theatres, universities, technical schools, shooting galleries,
playgrounds, gymnasiums, etc. Heat, light, and motive power, as well
as water might be conducted through our streets at public expense;
our roads be lined with fruit trees; discoverers and inventors
rewarded, scientific investigations supported; and in a thousand
ways the public revenues made to foster efforts for the public
benefit. We should reach the ideal of the Socialist, but not through
government repression. Government would change its character, and
would become the administration of I great co-operative society. It
would become merely the agency by which the common property was
administered for the common benefit."
No Socialist, we take it, hopes, at least for a long time, to
accomplish more than this. The question remains, is there anything in
the present practical proposals of the single taxer which is either
foreign to, or not directly tending towards, the Socialist's ideal?
The single taxer wishes to lax land values. This would take for the
community a portion of the value which the community created. It
would, in our view, do muck more, but looked at from (he point of view
of the Socialist, it should be of the first importance, for it both
reduces the value of the land, which he wishes ultimately to
nationalise, and provides a fund for purchase, or redeeming bonds paid
for the land, if he has purchase in view.
Again, the single taxer desires to nationalise, or municipalise,
railways, tramways, gasworks, waterworks, canals, telegraphs,
telephones, electric supply - all those undertakings, in fact, which
can be exploited by the individual only when some special privilege is
conferred upon him by the State. These are in their nature monopolies,
and to monopolies of almost every kind in the hands of the individual
the single taxer is a sworn foe. Such limited exceptions as copyright
and patents are of small importance.
Admitting that the Socialist considers this programme insufficient,
it surely, nevertheless, affords a basis for a working agreement which
would occupy reforming energies for the present and years to come. The
single taxer wishes to begin with an attack on land monopoly. Cannot
the Socialist go with him there? No one has pointed out more forcibly
than Karl Marx how potent an agent is land ownership in the
enslavement of labour. Let us destroy such ownership, and take the
next great step that may prove needful, when the ground is clear.
Private property in land cannot be abolished in a day, or in many
years, without unwearied effort, but the lime is propitious for
striking a telling blow. Government is in need of another 20,000,000
pounds to meet next year's demands on the revenue. A tax of 1d. on the
capital value of land in the United Kingdom, which cannot be less than
six thousand million pounds to-day, would supply the sum and about
5,000,000 pounds to spare.
Let wasteful expenditure be cut down, as it might and ought to be by
many millions, and still social reformers would find plenty of use for
the balance.
If space permitted, we could show how, besides raising revenue, this
tax would do much greater things in forcing land into use, in town and
country, which means employing men now unemployed, who in their turn
would spend their wages in employing others. We could show how it
would raise wages, by reducing the competition of men driven out of
the country with workers in the towns; how it would reduce rents, by
forcing owners of unoccupied land and houses to build and to secure
tenants.
These things, however, Socialists know. What we would urge upon them
is to put a tax upon land values in the forefront of their programme,
to make it their political battle cry for the coming months, and to
ask help of the hundreds and thousands of single taxers and land value
taxers, who are scattered throughout the country. They would be
surprised at the response. And if, when the first battle of the land
is won, question arises whether Radical and Socialist forces can still
advance together, at least they will understand one another's,
objectives better, after being comrades in arms.
MR. FELS AND THE SINGLE TAX
Nelson Field / 23 May 1912 (p.93)
Sir, - It is about time that Mr. Fels was informed that the measure
of his mind has been taken by Socialists; and they are no longer
inclined to be taken in by him. Day in, day out, we hear of Mr. Fels
popping a letter into this paper and inspiring an article in that,
subsidising a land-taxing lecturer here and a land-taxing party there,
and all with a single object, which he must be very insincere if he
conceals from himself. That object is to free his own class - the
class of industrial capitalists - from the incubus of rent. Oh, yes,
we understand our Mr. Fels better perhaps than he understands himself.
At present, industrial capitalists not only pay rent for their own
premises, but they must pay (in wages) the rents of their employees.
And to make bad worse, the rent thus extracted from them if spent by a
class that despises them. But suppose the State should appropriate
rent - a great deal of relief would come to Mr. Fels' caste in several
ways. First, rent would probably be reduced, if not for employers for
workmen - with the consequence that wanes might be reduced. Secondly,
the Government would spend its revenue from rent in the form of large
undertakings designed to provide still greater scope for capitalists.
Thirdly, a Single-tax is obviously designed to save the necessity of
other taxes. In other words, Mr. Fels would get a great relief! Go on,
Mr. Fels, we know your little game ; but it won't wash.
Fairplay / 6 June 1912 (p.93)
As I am not a Single Taxer, I am not influenced by political motives
in protesting against Mr. Field's unjustifiable attack. Nor does Mr.
Fels stand in need of any defence from me. 1 am animated merely by a
feeling of indignation at the injustice and unfairness oi this wanton
attack^ 1 enclose card.
MR. FELS AND THE SINGLE TAX
Nelson Field / 6 June 1912 (p.143)
Sir, - For all I know to the contrary, Mr. Fels may be, as your
correspondent, "Fairplay," affirms, the mildest- mannered
man that ever proposed to enrich himself at somebody's else's expense;
but King Charles I probably ran him very close, and even Mr. Fels'
enemies - the opponents of his Single-tax proposals - are probably not
without personal charm. But personal charm has nothing to do with
economics, and Mr. Fels ought to know very well that the release of
himself and his employees from the obligation of rack-rent and the
diversion of economic rent to the State will actually enable him to
increase his profits. Not only will his men's living minimum be
reduced, consequent on the reduction of their rent, but all the
philanthropic State undertakings, now in part paid for out of profits
and wages, will be paid by the State out of rent. Should private
capitalism therefore continue after the Single-tax is in operation -
and Mr. Fels has never suggested that it should not - the whole
benefits will fall to his class. The class of Rent will be abolished
only to make even more room for Interest and Profit. That Mr. Fels
does not expect personally to benefit during his lifetime by this
reform I can easily believe. If members of the capitalist class were
not individually prepared to be occasionally altruistic in the
interests of their class, the class itself would soon cease to exist;
there must be honour even among thieves.
Fair Play / 20 June 1912 (p.189)
Sir, - Mr. Nelson Field's opinion that the single tax will benefit
the capitalistic class by reducing rent and augmenting interest and
profits is a perfectly legitimate one. I have myself pointed out again
and again the absurdity of endeavoring to solve the industrial problem
by the simple application of Mr. Henry George's panacea, and have
exposed his contradictory assertions that "rent is robbery"
whilst "interest is natural and just." But when Mr. Field
goes on to impute dishonourable motives to those who accept George's
economic theories he is overstepping the bounds of decency. Your
correspondent has deliberately slandered a man he does not even know,
and after being told so by one who happens to know, he simply
reiterates the slander without any excuse. It is not necessary to
characterize such conduct as this. Mr. Fels is justified in treating
such "canaille" with contempt.
Nelson Field / 27 June 1912 (p.213)
Sir, - The would-be chivalrous personal defence your correspondent "Fair
Play" put up (or Mr. Fels led me to conclude at first that he was
no other that Mr. Fels; but his statement last week that in his
opinion the single tax would augment profits and interest makes my
assumption impossible. The dilemma "Fair Play" is now in is
clear; his friend Mr. Fels is spending money in propagating a proposal
that will be to his own advantage, or, at least, to the advantage of
his own profiteering business. Now, in what way, I should like to ask,
does Mr. Fels differ in this from the American trust magnates who go
into politics for the good of their business and even endow colleges
to spread economic fallacies? In America such men, however affable
their manners or apparently benevolent their actions, are described as
"out for boodle." Yet "Fair Play" objects to my
stating this of Mr. Fels, though he acknowledges that boodle in the
long run will result to Mr. Fels' class. What has an economist to do
with Mr. Fels' personal charm. The personal charm is not incompatible
with the economic instinct to squeeze out of society more interest and
profit and to name the process social reform. As a social reformer Mr.
Fels is either intellectually stupid not to see what "Fair Play"
and I see so clearly, or he is a shrewd, long-sighted business-man. If
this is slander, every economist daily slanders his thousands.
Nelson Field / 4 July 1912 (p.239)
Sir, - That amiable and charming gentleman, Mr. Fels, whom your
correspondent, "Fair Play," has known to his delight for
twenty years, shows no sign of profiting by "Fair Play's"
instructions in economics any more than by my "slanders " In
the "Daily Herald" of Tuesday last Mr. Fels returns to his
dead muttons like any vulture that has been momentarily scared off ;
and, after the usual manner of modern disputants, repeats his original
fallacies as if they had never been demonstrated to be such. Under the
title of "What Can the Rich Man do?" Mr. Fels perfunctorily
goes through a. list of obviously impossible charities which a
sensible rich man, like himself, cannot patronise. Omitting, then, any
charities or works of education or endowment that a rich man with
brains and good intentions might support, Mr. Fels hastens to his
appointed end of advocating the Single Tax. The real grievance of
labour to-day, he maintains, is that there are not jobs enough to go
round; and the reason of this is that land is held up from productive
exploitation. Tax landlords, therefore, on the market value of their
land, whether used or unused, and the latter variety will soon be
brought into the market. Doubtless it may be by this means; but what
is there to prevent the capitalist class, of which Mr. Fels is such an
amiable member, from intensifying their monopoly of Capital and Raw
Material? Obviously nothing. The class of Rent, in fact, is abolished
only to swell the classes of Interest and Profits, And since the
charming Mr. Fels belongs to one or both of these classes, his
interest in the Single Tax is personal. What can the rich man do,
therefore? He can employ his money in the propagation of reforms which
will add to his own wealth. When Jews do this, Mr. Belloc cries aloud
that England is being sold to the Israelites. But when an American
does it, and does it so amiably and so charmingly - being an amiable
and charming man and not one of those Jews - why, then "Fair
Play," and doubtless others, join in excusing him and in accusing
critics like myself of ''slander." Mr. Fels knows. better,
however, than to complain of " slander" himself. Neither the
Rothschilds nor he condescend to reply to criticisms to which there is
no honourable answer.
The Editors / 18 June 1912 (p.267)
From an interview with Mr. Finney in the "Labour Leader,"
and from his election literature that we have seen, we conclude that
Mr. Finney is a. moderate Liberal whereas Mr. Outhwaite is an advanced
Radical. In the "Labour Leader" Mr. Finney informs us that
he is in favour of a universal Minimum Wage Bill. So is Mr. Outhwaite.
He favours likewise an Eight Hours Day. So does Mr. Outhwaite. He
would nationalise the mines, etc. So would Mr. Outhwaite. Finally, he
summed up his programme in a poster issued during the election to this
effect: "Vote for Finney and better wages and regular work."
But Mr. Outhwaite is not only in favour of the same things, he has a
notion, though a bad one, of how to get them. He does not say: Vote
for me, and then when you have returned four hundred more like me, we
shall possibly be able to do something. No, he can say: Vote for me
and strengthen the hands of Mr. Lloyd George, who is about to do these
very things. In regard, therefore, not only to promises, but to the
ability to carry them out, the Liberal candidate had the advantage
over the Labour candidate. The latter, indeed, was in the anomalous
situation of having, on behalf of Labour, to oppose the main
constructive plank in Mr. Outhwaite's programme: the Single Tax. But
if the Single Tax was to be opposed - and we all agree that it should
be - all the rest of the social reform programme should be equally
opposed. To our mind the Single Tax differs in no essential respect
from the Minimum Wage, the Eight Hours Day, the Right to Work, and all
his other mites of the cheese. It is even conceivably a means of
financing these schemes at the expense of the landowner instead of at
the expense of the capitalist. But as both alike live on Labour the
difference in their effect on wages is the difference between
two-and-six and half-a-crown. Like the barbarians, however, who cannot
count, Mr. Finney put two-and-six on his programme, but he was shocked
at the suggestion of half-a-crown. Thus he and his supporters have
been made fools of by a party that, in the matter of social reform at
any rate, can beat them even hollower than they are.
Views and Reviews
A.E.R. / 27 February 1913 (p.409)
I DO not intend to deal with the "lies beyond"; there are
enough by the way. We know by past experience that, when the "manufacturers'
party" deals with the land, it tempers injustice with hypocrisy.
Cobden wrote to Mr. Peter Taylor, with reference to the agitation for
the repeal of the Corn Laws: "We don't want the question to be
argued, but to be taken up on the primitive grounds of right and
justice. We don't wish it to be treated as a manufacturer's question,
nor a capitalist's either; but as a bread tax that robs all the
community for the clumsy expedient of putting a mere fraction of the
booty into the pockets of the robbers." Yet it was a
manufacturer's question, for, four days later, Cobden wrote: "Eighteen
months ago the movement had its birth in the wrongs of a few
manufacturers who were seeking to be relieved from injuries inflicted
upon their own peculiar interests." These letters will be found
in Dr. Garnett's "Life of W. T. Fox." It behoves us to
remember these facts when we are asked to believe that Landlordism is
the primal curse, and to ask ourselves what we have to gain by
relieving the capitalist of all taxation, and raising the revenue of
the country by a single tax on land values. A Chartist in the hungry
'forties said of the manufacturers: "And now they want to get the
Corn Laws repealed -not for your benefit, but for their own. 'Cheap
bread,' they cry; but they mean 'Vow wages.' Do not listen to their
cant and humbug." We are now asked to believe that the Single Tax
means cheap land for everybody, whereas it only means lower ground
rents for manufacturers, with concomitant higher profits.
On the abstract grounds of right and justice, we have only to ask why
the whole cost of the national services should be borne by only one
section of the community to see the great injustice of the demand for
the Single Tax. Landlords, after all, do no more damage to the working
classes than do the manufacturers; and it must be admitted that the
national services are at present performed more for the benefit of the
manufacturers than of the landlords. We may grant that the private
ownership of land does not ensure the most productive use of it; we
may agree with Mr. Wedgwood that "the heavy rates upon houses,
machinery, stabling, sheds, glass-houses, etc., the 50 per cent,
exemption given to agricultural land, and the rebates on game-covers,
are all a very definite discouragement of production, and a distinct
encouragement to keep land vacant, or half-used, and cause a shortage
in it." But who made agricultural production so unremunerative
that a 50 per cent, exemption had to be granted? Who rushed the nation
into the towns, and forced up rents by the simple process of massing
people on comparatively small areas? Who but the manufacturers? Yet
they now come to us, in the person of Mr. Wedgwood, and tell us that
the road to freedom lies through agriculture, and that the only way to
obtain the land for the people is to increase its cost by making it
bear the whole taxation of the country.
It is argued by Mr. Wedgwood, as though he wished to demonstrate the
vindictiveness that inspires the attack on landlords, that a tax on
land cannot be shifted by the landlord on to the tenant. I care little
for what the "most respected economists" may say; Michael
Flurscheim, who devotes a chapter of his "Over-Production and
Want" to the land question, talks common sense on this point. For
the Single Tax, be it remembered, does not abolish the private
ownership of land: its prime objective is to force land into
productive use, and pay the whole cost of the national services. All
the rebates and exemptions will be transferred to manufacture. Against
the punitive intentions of the Single-Taxers, Flurscheim urges that, "though
it is true that, as a rule, the landlord takes all he can extort from
the tenant, this power of extortion depends in the last resort on the
rent-paying power of the latter. Now, as any tax relief obtained by
the tenant raises his rent-paying power, the landlord may certainly
recoup, by a higher rent, any tax shifted on his shoulders from those
of the tenant. If a tenant pays $300 rent and $50 taxes, and you make
the landlord pay the $50 taxes, will not the rent rise to $350?
There is a statement made by Mr. Wedgwood himself that betrays the
fallacy of his argument that the Single Tax will destroy the monopoly
of the ownership of land. "Many of that minority," he says, "who
exclusively possess the control of portions of the earth's surface,
have not only occupied what will satisfy their own needs, but have
also exercised their monopoly power of withholding from use, so as to
keep other land vacant or half-used. They have no necessary inducement
or need to do otherwise; and that it is actually done is shown by the
fact that many country landlords get no more than 2 per cent, on the
capital value of their land; thus proving that ownership, without even
normal return, is all they want." If already landowners are
content with 2 per cent., why should we suppose that they would resign
their ownership, even if the 2 per cent, were denied them? It has
already been predicted that England will gradually be turned into the
pleasure domain of the world's aristocracy and plutocracy; and
Flurscheim argues that the Single Tax could not prevent this
conversion, "Suppose that, under the Single Tax," he says, "the
Rothschilds and a few hundred other millionaires in England and
America should share the whim of turning Great Britain into a
deer-park, and British landlords should sell at reasonable figures
because of the new tax, which destroys the selling value of their
land. Under existing laws, what could prevent these men from having
their will? Certainly not the land-value tax, even if it were as high
as it would be were the present values taken as a basis of
calculation, i.e., 200 million pounds a year. The income of
Rockefeller and Carnegie alone is at present valued at 12 to 15
million pounds each; that of the Rothschild families is higher, and,
without going any further, we have already obtained one-quarter of the
yearly tax required. But how long would it be required? How long would
there be a rental value of 200 million pounds in a depopulated
England, in that magnificent new deer-park? That value would follow
British enterprise wherever the evicted people went. The United
States, Australia, New Zealand, Canada, South Africa, would see their
land values rise as the British land values fell; and finally the 200
millions might be reduced to something like 5s. an acre, to 20 million
pounds, or even less, a mere trifle for such magnates. That such an
event is practically impossible is begging the question, because it is
only saying in other words that the Single Tax is impossible."
Into Flurscheim's arguments for land nationalisation by purchase I
cannot enter here; but enough has been said to show that, if land
monopoly is the root of all evil, as Mr. Wedgwood argues, and I am
willing to agree, the evil cannot be abolished by the Single Tax,
which, at the best, could only exchange a small number of private
owners for a large number, and, at the worst, would enable industrial
capitalists to complete the ruin of England by purchasing the land at
forced prices. Already, as Mr. Wedgwood shows, industrial capitalists
are becoming landowners abroad; and the process may well be repeated
here if the Single Tax be imposed on land. By the abolition of the
landlord, the capitalist producer would be freed from the burden of
monopoly rent; and the Single Tax would simplify for him the question
of the charges on industry. But with capital and land in the hands of
the same people, the workers of England would be as badly off as ever.
THE SINGLE TAX
M. Fairley / 13 March 1913 (p.462)
Sir, - As your review of "The Road to Freedom" is a
criticism of the Single Tax, with a direct attack on the bona-fides of
Single Taxers, perhaps you will allow me a few words in reply. While
it is always useful to scrutinise carefully the motives of a party who
bring forward a measure, the measure, nevertheless, stands on its own
legs as a step towards justice or the reverse; in other words, the
thing advocated has nothing whatever lo do with the advocate.
Who. for example, would delay the abolition of slavery (industrial or
chattel) because it happened to be brought forward by a man or a party
who were not always just in their dealings with their fellow-man?
The first effect of the Single Tax is seen in the answer to the
question: What is the difference in position between a
tenant who pays the economic rent of his holding to a landlord,
who in turn hands it over to the State, and a landlord who pays the
economic rent of his estate to the State? Answer: There is no
difference.
The second effect is seen if we ash how the landlord is to pay the
economic rent unless he works the land to the full. He is now merely a
tenant of the State, and no tenant can afford to keep any but a very
small fraction of his land idle - i.e., he must, like all other
tenants, work his land to the full, it necessary getting others to
help him. Should he be unable to get sufficient help, he will be laced
with a forced sale, which will reduce the selling price to the
vanishing point. Now, the worker has no interest in the selling price
of land, but he must have the use of land or perish. He can now get
the use of land on condition that he pays the economic rent to the
State, which is all that is necessary to ensure that each man will get
the full product of his own labour and that the community will get the
reward of their communal labour, which is the economic rent or Single
Tax.
In conclusion, the Single Taxers have a definite programme mapped
out, and have now got in Australia and Canada small instalments of
their reform actually carried out, often in the teeth of the
opposition of capitalists and landlords. Here, in this country, we
have strenuous opposition from manufacturers, landowners, and
Socialists.
The workers are eagerly looking for light and lending. You have
admitted that "land monopoly is the root of all evil." It is
now up to the Socialists to formulate a definite programme and policy,
with the means or method of carrying it out, with which they can
appeal to the people for their judgment and support. Let them fail in
this, and they fail to justify their existence as reformers. The time
for ideals is past. What we want is something done.
THE SINGLE TAX
A.E.R. / 20 March 1913 (p.487)
Sir, - Mr. Fairley's letter has puzzled me. He tells me that, "while
it is always useful to scrutinise carefully the motives of a party who
bring forward a measure, the measure, nevertheless, stands on its own
legs as a step towards justice or the reverse; in other words, the
thing advocated has nothing whatever to do with the advocate."
This is an astounding affirmation, so far as politics is concerned;
for we know that the clearest and most determinate principle means
different things to different people. The recent case of insurance
against sickness is an example. Most doctors would hold that you could
only insure people against sickness by keeping them in good health,
and would argue that any scheme that made provision for perfunctory
medical treatment of disease or disability was not really insurance.
The mass of insured people would argue that any scheme that reduced
their income during health to provide them with a still smaller income
during sickness was not an insurance against sickness in any
intelligible sense of the word. To Mr. Lloyd George, insurance against
sickness means "nine-pence for fourpence," and a whole host
of unimaginable and unrealisable blessings for the people. If "the
thing advocated has nothing whatever to do with the advocate,"
considering the changeling nature of political propaganda and its
results, I can only demand that each new advocate shall "table
his Bill" before I pretend to know what he advocates.
Certainly, in the else of the Single Tax, some such precaution is
needed, for it is argued both by Henry George and the Socialists that
private property in land is the root of all our trouble. But the
Single Tax, proposed by Henry George, would not abolish private
property in land; the landlord would still be the landlord, and the
user of the land would still have to bear all charges, including the
Single Tax, laid on the land. That, I think, was sufficiently
demonstrated by the passages I quoted from Flurscheim. But I am now
asked; "What is the difference in position between a tenant who
pays the economic rent of his holding to a landlord, who, in turn,
hands it over to the State, and a landlord who pays the economic rent
of his estate to the State?"; and I am told that there is no
difference whatever. There is one important and fundamental difference
between the two propositions, for the alternative assumes that
Socialism has been established and that the land has been
nationalised. As a matter of fact, neither of these things has
happened in England, nor are they contemplated by the advocates of the
Single Tax. The Single Tax is not proposed as a means to the abolition
of private property in land (the Socialist solution), hut as a means
of abolishing monopoly rents, which hit shopkeepers and manufacturers
rather hardly.
I am next told that the landlord cannot pay the economic rent
(although the Single Tax is not economic rent) unless he works his
land (o the full. I quoted Mr. Wedgwood to show that the landlord
cares more for possession than for profit, and that the Single Tax
would not make him relinquish possession. I quoted Flurscheim to show
that even the economic rent of land could be paid by the landlord, and
still the land need not be worked to the full. I have the more
pleasure in quoting the following extract from the "Daily
Chronicle," March 12, 1913, because Mr. Fairley tells me that, in
Canada, the Single Taxers have got a small instalment of their reform
actually in practice. The "Daily Chronicle" says: "The
Duke of Sutherland is one of those British landlords who are buying
great stretches of land in Canada. He is, however, also selling some
of his estates in this country, and just recently Mr. J. W. Stewart, a
wealthy Scotsman, who emigrated to Canada, has bought over 50,000
acres of the Duke's Sutherland shire estates. . . .
Mr. Stewart is, of course, acquiring the Sutherlandshire estates
more or less as a luxury, while the Duke is buying land in Canada as
an investment." The italics are mine. Mr. Stewart evidently
does not believe that the Single Tax will he imposed on his estates in
Sutherland, and evidently docs not intend to work his land to the
full, for he has acquired them "more or less as a luxury."
On the other hand, the Duke of Sutherland actually finds that Canada,
where the Single Tax is already in operation to some extent, is a more
desirable place for investment in land than England. I think that I
need not argue abstract economic questions when a fact of this
importance is to hand.
Mr. Fairley tells me that "the worker has no interest in the
selling price of land." Flurscheim, referring to the working of
the Ashbourne Acts, quotes from the "Times," January 28,
1890: "One tenant bought the farm he cultivated at £550, and
soon sold it, subject to the repayment of this sum", for 970
pounds. Another farm bought for 538 pounds was sold, subject to the
purchase money, for £1,280. One which had fetched £755 was
sold by the fortunate tenant who obtained possession of it through the
new law, subject to the purchase money, for £1,725.'' It is clear
that, unless private property in land is abolished, the worker may
have a considerable interest in the selling price of land; and as the
Single Tax will not abolish private ownership, and will only be
burdensome to working farmers, it will be the worker, not the large
landowner, who "will be faced with a forced sale, which will
reduce the selling price of land to the vanishing point," at
which price the people who want land more or less as a luxury will be
pleased to buy.
I am told that "it is now up to the Socialists to formulate a
definite programme and policy, with the means or the method of
carrying it out, with which they can appeal to the people for their
judgment and support." Programmes and policies belong to
political parties, and there is no political Socialist Party in
England; so that Mr Fairley's demand falls on air. If Mr. Fairley
wants to know the Socialist solution of the problem, he can read the
book, by Alfred Russell Wallace, or the publications of the English
Land Nationalisation Society, or the chapter on Land in Michael
Flurscheim's "Over-production and Want." He may also be
recommended to read the series of articles on Guild-Socialism now
appearing in THE NEW AGE. If he really wants something done, and that
something to be beneficial, I can only advise him to restrain his
impatience and study a subject before he accepts a solution; and if "the
time for ideals is past," as he says, to remember that the Single
Tax is only an ideal, that it is not practical politics, that, if it
ever becomes so in England, it will leave the land in private
possession, and will add nothing to the welfare of the people. For it
is, or should be, clear that taxation (whether single or multiple) by
a capitalistic State is simply the means whereby that State is
maintained; and if one set of monopolists uses the State for the
destruction of another set of monopolists, the result is that monopoly
becomes more monopolistic; and if monopoly is the evil, the last state
is worse than the first.
SINGLE TAX
M. Fairley / 10 April 1913 (p.564)
Sir, - I heartily agree with Mr. A.E.R. that "the clearest and
most determinate principle means different things to different people,"
and on this account only I Should like to answer his letter, as his
idea of the Single Tax and the idea that Single Taxers have of that
measure Seem to differ.
We say that (1) the rental value (or the annual value of the land
taken independently of all improvements) is being created day by day
by the presence and activity of those who work and is created by
nothing else; (2) that those people have the sole right to take this
value and to Spend it on their communal needs.
Ask, therefore, everyone who says that he owns a piece of land to
state what its rental value is and to pay to the State that rental
value, whether that land is used or unused. This we maintain is just
and equitable. Now the only reason that this measure is called the
Single Tax is that it would be collected by the same machinery as
taxes are collected. But you can call it "The taking for the
community of the Rent of the Land," if that title is more
pleasing.
I would like now to note one or two minor points in your
correspondent's letter which I think should be cleared up. He says, "The
Single Tax is not economic rent." Quite so, but, as explained
above, the Single Tax will take the economic rent which is the rent of
a piece of land whether used or not.
Re Canada, I should, apparently, have explained that only in certain
districts do we find an instalment of the Single Tax in force. In the
State of Alberta all towns and over fifty rural municipalities levy
their local rates on land values, i.e., they take a portion of the
rental value for the communal needs. In Saskatchewan, the position is
about the same; British Columbia are introducing the principle on a
small scale at present, but will probably follow the lead of Alberta.
Australia would require a page to itself. These facts should, I think,
be known to every social reformer and stock taken of the facts as the
movement grows. I have not been able to find out whether the Duke of
Sutherland's estates come under the influence of this measure; it
would be of equal interest to know what be thinks of it. We know what
the late Duke of Argyll thought of Henry George's proposal. He said: "If
all owners of land, great and small, might be robbed, and ought to be
robbed of that which society had from time immemorial allowed them and
encouraged them to acquire and call their own; if the thousands of
men, women and children who directly and indirectly live on rent ...
are all equally to be ruined by the confiscation of the fund on which
they depend - are there not other funds which would be all swept into
the Same net of envy and of violence?" The Duke bad no doubt
about the effect of the Single Tax.
One other point. From the official tax on New York City, which I have
before me, the valuators separate the land value from the value of
improvements (stone and lime, furniture, jewels, etc.), although no
land value tax is levied so far. Now in that city the capital land
value stands at 1,000 million pounds sterling, and is 62.6 per cent,
of the whole, leaving 37.4 per cent, representing capital value of
labour products. In the light of this, your correspondent's estimate
of the total land value of Great Britain at 200 million pounds per
annum seems rather small, for 200 by 20 years gives only 4,000 million
pounds capital value, or four times only that of the city of New York.
Space forbids going into the enormous mineral land values of this
country, which ought to pay their full economic rent to the community.
A.E.R. / 10 April 1913 (p.564)
A.E.R. replies: - Mr. Fairley tells me that the Single Tax is a tax
on rental value up to its limit as declared; I knew that. Mr. Wedgwood
told me the same thing. But in what way is this proposal superior to
the proposal for taxing incomes up to their limit as declared? In what
way is the Single Tax superior to any other tax pushed to its extreme?
Why not tax bachelors up to the whole of their income; why not tax
bicycles, or gramophones, or motor cars, or musical comedies, up to
the limit of their declared value? Is it not obvious that bachelors
would be less able to marry than they now are, and that motor cars,
etc., would either be double their present price, or would not be
produced at all? The bachelors, like the land, could not escape the
tax, except by suicide: the land cannot even commit suicide. But if
land is unused, how can it have a rental value? The imposition of the
Single Tax on unused land is not impossible ; nothing is impossible to
vindictive people; but it would be absolutely unproductive of revenue.
It is an axiom in a Free Trade country that we tax for revenue, and as
unused land can yield up revenue, the Exchequer will not be
replenished from this source. It a value is given to unused land by a
Government vainer, and a tax levied on that value, then it is obvious
that we are not taxing for revenue, but for some punitive purpose. If
the idea is to force this land into use, then it may well be defeated
by that passion for possession which Mr. Wedgwood mentioned, and which
Alfred Russell Wallace has declared to be the characteristic of rich
people. If the land is forced into use, is it not obvious that the
user will pay the tax? If, at the present time, with a 50 per cent,
remission on agricultural land, the farmer cannot get a living in this
country, how much will agriculture be improved when the land has to
bear all the Charges of the State? I do not deny, I never have denied,
that the Single Tax is a fiscal proposal, and can be imposed like any
other tax; what I deny is that its results will abolish the evils of
land monopoly. Mr. Wedgwood argued that the Single Tax would improve
agriculture, stop the harmful growth of industrialism, raise wages,
and free the workers from all monopolists. I have given my reasons for
supposing that it will do nothing of the sort, that, on the contrary,
at its best it will only simplify the incidence of taxation; at its
worst, it will unify the monopolies of land and capital. If Mr.
Fairley wants to ignore my arguments, he may; but he cannot expect me
to continue the discussion. I do not intend to repeat what I have
said; I cannot quote in your pages the whole of Flurscheim's arguments
against the Single Tax, nor can 1 reprint the book by Alfred Russel
Wallace. If Mr. Fairley will not read for himself: he must remain a
Single-Taxer; I have nothing more to say to him.
SINGLE TAX AND PROFITEERING
Joseph Fels / 11 September 1913 (p.582)
Sir, - Your Open Letter addressed to the Trades Union Congress
emphasises the importance of the figures provided by the recent Board
of Trade inquiry into working-class rents and retail prices. You
conclude that, because prices have advanced 13.7 per cent., while
rents of dwellings have advanced only 1.8 per cent., therefore the
real enemy is what you call the "profiteer" and not the
landlord.
If you claim that the Board of Trade inquiry proves the absolute gain
to the landlords to have been only 1.8 per cent., and that "manufacturers
are extorting more than landlords" out of the workers, I think
you arrive swiftly at most absurd conclusions. For what you say
regarding the difference between money wages and "real"
wages must be true also of money profits and rents and "real"
profits and rents. In each case the " real " income is not
the money received, but the goods that can be purchased with such
money.
The Board of Trade inquiry includes the prices of beef, mutton, pork,
tea, sugar, bacon, cheese, butter, potatoes, flour, bread, milk, and
coal. These goods are purchased not only by the money received by the
wage earner. They are also purchased by the money received by the
landlord and by the money received by the " profiteer."
Now, if you contend that the landlord-robber has succeeded in
increasing his extortion by only 1.8 per cent., despite Single Tax
accusations of "rapacity," his gain must likewise be offset
by the rise in prices. With his rent increased by 1.8 per cent., he
has to pay 13.7 per cent, more for all the goods I have enumerated
above, and on the average his " real " rent has actually
diminished, just as "real " wages have diminished.
Applying this same strange argument of yours to the case of the "
profiteer," it is apparent his benefit has been more imaginary
than real. He has had to pay increased money wages varying from 1.9
per cent, for skilled builders to 4.1 per cent, for compositors. But
he does not sell all the goods catalogued in the Board of Trade
inquiry. Many "profiteers" sell none of them. At the best,
the "profiteer " sells only a few, and for these he receives
prices increased by 13.7 per cent.,
but he has to purchase all the rest and pay 13.7 per cent, more
for them. Therefore, on your own showing, and making the same use
as you do of the Board of Trade figures, his "real" profits
have been considerably diminished. One "profiteer" has
blackmailed and robbed another, and your contention that either
landowner or "profiteer" has been enriched is flatly denied.
It should occur to you that there is a fallacy in considering that
the rent paid by wage-earners for house room, after receiving their
wages, is the only payment landlords extort from them and from the
results of their labour. Yet that is the basis of your whole argument,
and it is your reason for rejecting the assurances of the "satellites
of the manufacturing employer" that the cause of the increased
cost of living is landlordism.
Yon define wages as "the price paid in the competitive market
for labour as a commodity." This is not a definition, for it does
not include the considerable number of workers whose earnings are no
greater than those of "factory hands" and who are not in the
pay of any employer. But however wages may be defined, there is no
disputing the fact that they are that part of the total wealth
produced from year to year which is received by wealth producers,
whether in the pay of employers or not. True, they are only a small
part, and the distribution of wealth is unequal and unjust; but who
gets the balance not received by wage-earners? You will not maintain
it is all collared in " profits" by the so-called "profiteer."
You yourself distinguish, when pointing the finger of scorn at the "Single
Taxer," between the "profiteer" and the landlord,
although in other parts of your Open Letter the distinction between
the owner of plant, machinery, and buildings, and the owner of land is
more obscure. You will not maintain that the landowner gets no part of
the surplus which is not received by wage-earners, for you must grant
that a large part of this surplus is secured by landowners as tribute
for the permission to use the earth.
No "profiteer" has yet been able to exploit a landowner. It
is the landowner who exploits the "profiteer," and he can
screw up his tribute to the highest point any industry can bear by
keeping his hold on the monopoly of land, and allowing only some sites
and some areas to be used.
It is after the landowner has received this tribute, after rates and
taxes have been paid for the sin of erecting buildings or installing
machinery, after every effort is made to pass on these burdens to the
consumer, that wages are paid. The produce of the factory, mine, or
farm must provide the incomes of all and the revenue of the State. The
community as a whole is robbed by the landowner, even though the
so-called "profiteer" acts as go-between and pays the rent.
If by "profiteer" you mean anyone and everyone who employs
a fellow-being, your quarrel cannot be with the "profiteer"
as such. For great numbers of employers are scarcely better off than
those whom they employ. They live from hand to mouth, have no special
privileges, no monopoly, and no patent rights. Your quarrel manifestly
is with a particular kind of "profiteer," especially the "
great employing manufacturer "or the "large capitalist,"
who can generally afford to look on while other men do the work. The
vice of the argument is that you do not distinguish among the "profiteers"
who own (a) only buildings, plant, or machinery, (b) only land, (c)
both land and buildings, plant or machinery. Most "large
capitalists" belong to the third class. Part of their assets
consists in land and a corresponding part of their profits is pure
rent of land. Cement firms and salt firms, for instance, generally
take good care to own the deposits of raw material upon which their
industry is based, while landless labourers, deprived of all rights to
these or any other natural resources, beg at the factory gates for the
privilege of a job.
You quite rightly insist upon the great increase in the production of
wealth, which is, as you state, proved by every test; but I repeat,
you have to point the moral by showing who has pocketed the increase.
You cannot use the term "profiteer," for it is abundantly
clear that this term is a confusion. The balance, except for what is
paid strictly in salaries and such peculiar payments as patent
royalties, has been divided between interest and rent -interest upon
stock-in-trade, buildings, plant, and machinery, and rent of land. But
as stock-in-trade, buildings, plant, and machinery are being
constantly reproduced, and as the owners of these things are
constantly competing with one another, they cannot claim anything but
the market rate of interest.
But land is not reproduced. It is limited absolutely in area. It is
the essential condition of all existence. Its owners charge tribute
for its use without giving anything whatever in return, or pocket a
large part of the produce as rent and call it profits on their "investment."
The more that can be produced on land, the greater is the tribute, so
long as the monopoly is maintained - and repeated illustrations prove
to the hilt how effectively both the dreadful "capitalist"
and the common labourer can be "exploited" in this way.
The increased production has gone in rent. But you would disguise
this fact with obvious confusions in terms. You would practise
deception in trying to persuade the workers, on the authority of a
Blue Book that proves nothing of the kind, that the landlord receives
nothing but the few shillings a week paid by each wage earner for
house room. When yon discuss your final proposals for abolishing the "bondage
of wagery," you sink the landlord out of sight and advocate "a
reasonable annuity for two generations to the owners of plant and
machinery." Are your readers to gather that a "reasonable
annuity" is also your method of dispensing compensation to
landowners? If not, what do you propose to do in regard to the rent
now paid for laud, and also in regard to the value of land for which
no rent is paid because it is held out of use?
There are several considerations in regard to labour and wages I wish
you to look at. Firstly, labourers are employed by other labourers.
The producer of boots is employed by the wearer of boots, who in
return produces bread or furniture or clothes. If producers of bread
are prevented from producing, there is correspondingly less employment
for the makers of boots and vice versa. The real employer of the bus
driver is not the bus company, but the people who ride in buses. Every
employed man makes a demand for the goods produced or services
provided by other employed men.
Secondly, the general level of wages can never be more than the
earnings men can get in the least productive occupation or on the
least productive land. The condition of the man on the "margin,"
as both Mr. Shaw and Mr. Webb have shown, determines the condition of
men in all other employments. The wage-earner will get the same wages
whether he is employed by the greatest capitalistic concern or by the
humblest and most self-sacrificing shopkeeper in a back street. So
that, although wages are "a price paid for a commodity,"
they are not less than what wage earners can get in the least
productive employment.
Thirdly, labourers, as you say, are too plentiful. But plentiful in
relation to what? Certainly not in relation to the fund in the
possession of the "profiteer," which is apparently your
meaning - an implicit statement of the wage fund theory that wages are
determined by the amount of capital that could be devoted to the
employment of labourers. In obedience to that theory, you would "capture"
all capital for the guilds, and thus make labour the master of the
situation. But the theory was blown sky-high thirty years ago by Henry
George, who demonstrated that wages are determined by the number
of labourers seeking employment in relation to the number of available
natural opportunities open to labour. It is only if these natural
opportunities are scarce that labour will be "plentiful" and
will find difficulty in securing employment. And as everyone has an
equal right to the use of natural opportunities, the proper course is
to destroy monopoly in them by obliging every holder to pay their
annual value to the rest of the community.
That means the taxation and rating of land values, for every "natural
opportunity" is laud in some form or other, whether it is the
site of a house, an area suitable for a farm, coal deposits, slate
quarries, or river water. The value of land represents the wealth
which belongs to the community as a whole, and in appropriating it for
the community we would not only "pool" this wealth, but we
would force monopolists to let go the land they hold out of use, and
thus multiply the available natural opportunities. It is only by
giving each man an equal right "margin," all the surplus
wealth which is produced on superior sites and soils being pooled for
common benefit. In other words, there are more labourers to-day than
there are opportunities for employment. The taxation of land values
would, we insist, annex the wealth that belongs to all, expel the land
speculator, and open to labour the limitless opportunities in town and
country which Nature provides. This would make opportunities more
plentiful than labourers, and raise wages, just as existing conditions
of monopoly in these opportunities restrict employment and force wages
to subsistence level with each labourer's effective demand for goods
correspondingly curtailed.
Editors / 11 September 1913 (p.581-582)
[We willingly reply in some detail to this letter, although we know
that Mr. Fels is a fanatic upon the subject. We will, however, assume
that he is amenable to reason.]
It is primarily necessary to impress upon Mr. Fels the fact, well
known to our regular readers, that we have no more feeling of sympathy
for the landlords than for the profiteers. Both in their own way
(which in the final analysis is very much the same' way) exploit
labour. Mr. Fels complains that our distinction between rent and
interest tends to become obscure. It is not for us to draw fine
distinctions between the two. As a Single Taxer, Mr. Fels is
penetrated with the belief that there are fundamental distinctions
between the functions of the profiteering and land-owning classes. We
do not deny that a profiteer, functioning as an administrator, differs
in economic significance from a landlord who lives solely upon rent.
But it is the same distinction on the other foot when we have a
landlord functioning as an administrator compared with a profiteer who
lives solely upon profits. The effects of the exploitation of labour
by landlord and profiteer are precisely the same, so far as the wage
slave is concerned. The French with logical clearness decline to make
the distinction. A "rentier " draws his income from "rentes,"
precisely as he draws it from rent. Mr. Fels, not being a regular
reader of THE NEW AGE (a moral lapse which we trust he will rectify),
assumes that our whole attack is upon the profiteer. Accordingly he
asks whether we are prepared to mete out the same justice to landlords
as to profiteers when we advocate "a reasonable annuity for two
generations." Of course we are. It shocks us to discover that Mr.
Fels should have any doubt about it. But in the struggle to abolish
wagery (the continuance of which Mr. Fels complacently accepts) we
have deemed it wise to preserve a sense of proportion. If the
profiteers exploit labour to a greater extent than do the landlords,
then palpably the profiteer is the more serious enemy of the two. That
was the point of our remark that drew this reply from Mr. Fels, who
believes that the imposition of a single tax upon the land values "would
annex the wealth that belongs to all, expel the land speculator, and
open to labour the limitless opportunities in town and country which
Nature provides. This would make opportunities more plentiful than
labourers and raise wages." Mr. Fels, in short, invites us to
leave the profiteer alone and concentrate our attack upon the
landlord. But he admits that, after the Single Tax had done its deadly
work, the wage system would continue. As the wage system is equally
fundamental to the existence of both landlord and profiteer, and as we
desire the destruction of wagery, we are not so foolish as to make
flesh of the profiteer and fowl of the landlord. Both separately and
in alliance they exploit labour by maintaining the wage system. So far
as Mr. Fels believes in the continuance of wagery, he writes himself
down an enemy of labour, and so clouds with suspicion his personally
well-intentioned attack upon the landlords. We are therefore fully
justified in warning the trade unionists against his particular
propaganda. His letter completely proves the wisdom of our remark. Mr.
Fels can only come into court with clean hands when he frankly accepts
the justice and policy of wage abolition.
Before touching upon some of the details in his letter, we must
remind Mr. Fels that the new conception of society from which wages
are eliminated necessarily transforms the meaning of many economic
terms. For example, to the wage earner, rent, interest, and profits
connote the economic power which the possessing classes exercise upon
the proletariat. The deduction (adumbrated by Ricardo) is this : rent
is in reality the economic power that one man or class exercises upon
another. Thus a man with £100 in gold at the bank rents it out
for £5 perr annum. Another man with land valued at £100
rents it out at £5 per annum. The economic effect is precisely
the same in both instances. Both, in fact, exact rent. The Single
Taxers seem to think that the £5 exacted in the form of interest
smells differently from the £5 exacted as rent. Our sense of
smell, aided by reason and instinct, rejects any such theory. And in
abstract justice we cannot morally distinguish between the two
transactions.
There are some statements of fact in Mr. Fels' letter that call for
comment. He quite rightly points out that the increase in rent of 1.8
per cent, must be offset by the advance in prices of 13.7 per cent.
Therefore "real" rent has diminished. We believe this to be
absolutely the fact, but how it helps Mr. Fels we are at a loss to
understand. The landlord, certainly in all large transactions, rents
his land on lease. If the cost of living advances, he cannot raise his
rent. But the profiteer can, in association with his commercial
colleagues, raise his prices once a month or once a year. To him it is
largely a question of associated effort. If, then, "real"
rents have actually diminished and "real" wages have fallen,
somebody has run off with the plunder. We assert that it is the
profiteers, whose income as a class has steadily risen in recent years
up to 22% per cent. Granting the 13.7 per cent, advance in the cost of
living, this gives the profiteering class a net advance of 9 per
cent., which is precisely the percentage of the fall in real wages.
Why, then, should we point our guns only at the landlords, when
obviously the profiteers have the heaviest artillery? Mr. Fels cries
mercy for the profiteers because they apparently blackmail and rob
each other. No doubt they do; but profiteers of every denomination, in
happy unity with the landlords, are all agreed that they must maintain
the wage system so that they may exploit labour. Mr. Fels is in that
galley. If we can sink it, he, too, will go down. At the Judgment Day
he will get short shrift if he contends that we ought first to have
sunk some other galley in the same fleet.
The truth, however, is that Mr. Fels does not know the true meaning
of wages. He rejects one definition because "it does not include
the considerable number of workers whose earnings are no greater than
those of 'factory hands' and who are not in the pay of any employer."
The simple answer, of course, is that they do not receive wages - the
small shopkeeper, for example. But it is not our definition; it is the
classical definition from Adam Smith to Marx. The term "wage"
has a distinct and well-understood meaning, and Mr. Fels must accept
it if he would publicly discuss any subject in which the wage system
is included.
It is this inability on the part of Mr. Fels to appreciate the exact
meaning of wages that leads him into another extraordinary blunder. He
quite truly asserts that many profiteers are scarcely better off than
those they employ. Therefore, he argues, "your quarrel manifestly
is with a particular kind of profiteer, especially the great employing
manufacturer or the large capitalist." Nothing we have written
gives Mr. Fels any sanction for such a statement. Our quarrel is not
with the individual profiteers, whether great or small, but with the
system. The system permits every class and kind and degree of
profiteer to buy labour as a commodity at a competitive price finally
based on the subsistence level. Between the price paid for the labour
commodity plus the price of the other raw material and the selling
price of the finished product, landlord and profiteer are provided
for. We tell the wage earner so to organize that he shall possess a
monopoly of labour power, then to decline to sell his labour as a
commodity and at all costs to retain his right (i.e., his economic
power) in the product created by his labour. By organising himself
into appropriate guilds he can thereby squeeze out rent, interest, and
profits. In this squeezing-out process, both landlords and profiteers
will be heard squealing. Which squeals first is only of academic
interest to us. The purchase of labour as a commodity for exploitation
is a sin and an abomination, not to be distinguished from chattel
slavery. The Single Taxers do not appear to realise this, and are
accordingly guilty of moral obtuseness.
Mr. Fels, for some reason we cannot grasp, next remarks that we
implicitly accept the wage-fund theory. As Marx smashed the wage-fund
theory a generation ago, and as our definition of wages has literally
nothing whatever to do with this dead theory, and as, incidentally, we
killed the theory ourselves in our series on the Wage-System, we
appeal to Mr. Fels to believe that we are not utter ignoramuses. We
solemnly assure him that Jeremy Bentham was dead before we were born.
The exact politico-economic situation that would be created by the
successful imposition of the single-tax would be simply this: the
profiteers would possess their present economic power plus the
security of tenure they would obtain from State-rented land. As
economic power precedes political power, they would be enabled to
reduce or increase rents precisely as it suited their purposes. Rent,
in the ordinary acceptation of the word to the profiteer, is a
subsidiary, indeed almost a. negligible consideration. Mr. Fels thinks
land would become so accessible to labour that the labourer would find
available "natural opportunities," and so be able to secure
higher wages. He bases this conclusion, so far as we can gather, on
the assumption that whereas "buildings, plant, and machinery are
being constantly reproduced" (therefore requiring large command
of capital) "land is not reproduced." Therefore the ordinary
capitalistic processes do not operate in agriculture, and accordingly,
free access to the land spells freedom from capitalistic oppression.
As a matter of fact, so long as wagery is the foundation of our
industrial system, capitalistic processes are as necessary to
agriculture as to industry. Economically considered land does
reproduce itself. If it does not, how does it "run down"? If
it does not, why the necessity for periodic fallow? If it does not,
why have 250,000 farmers left the Middle West and migrated to Canada?
Has Mr. Fels ever heard of manure? We are really forced to the
conclusion that when the single-taxers discuss land they are all as
mad as March hare.
|