The Determination of Rent
A Discussion of the Mathematics and Theoretical Assertions
Involved
Fred Foldvary, David Hillary and Dan Sullivan
[Reprinted from a Land-Theory online
discussion, October 2000]
DAN SULLIVAN
Fred
makes a shift in the meaning of growth rate. |
David
Hillary responds:
Please note that I have always used g to be the rate of growth of
(gross) rent, as defined in my proof. Fred appears to have changed
his tune, I have not. |
DAN SULLIVAN
The obvious solution to making the formula work
properly is to define g as a growth in *net* rent, for it is net
rent, not gross rent, that interests the investor. The price will,
in turn, be projected from the expected gain in net rent. Of
course, this is what David called "bullshit," but the
numbers work. |
David
Hillary responds:
Earlier in this post (whoops deleted it) you
stated that it was wrong to employ in a function an argument which
depended on the function, as a solution for stating the function's
value. There is a grain of truth in this assertion. However in the
above part of your post you state that the rate of growth of the
net rent should be used in the value function. However with value
taxation, the net rent depends on the value through time. If the
price-rent ratio is constant and the rent growth rate is constant
this may be admissable.
If you want to prove a land value function you will need to
define value in an acceptable way and move from this definition of
value to your final formula using valid steps. I define value of
an asset as being equal to the sum of the discounted expected net
income. Then I express the income in terms of gross rent less tax
in each period. Then I solve for the value. i.e.:
Pn=f(Ii)=sum{i=n to inf}((Ii)*(1+d)^(n-i-1))
Ii=Ri-Ti
Ri=R0*(1+g)^i
Ti=t*Pi
and so on to get
d=y-t+g at the end.
|
DAVID HILLARY
Dan,
it's time you conformed to some mathematical and logical
conventions such as stating your premesis and using a valid
argument form. Until then its hard to refrain from describing your
claims as "complete bullshit." |
DAN SULLIVAN
Actually, Fred is right that Solow's formula
works if we redefine "g", but we must redefine it not
from growth in rent to growth in price, but from growth in gross
rent to growth in net rent.
After all, just as the current investor is interested in net
rent, not gross rent, so is the price dependent on what future
investors will be interested in, and they, too, will be interested
in net rent, not gross rent.
This is where David went astray initially. He projected a
perpetual growth in price based on a perpetual growth in gross
rent, even though he figured the tax collectors to be collecting
the entire rent. Hence, the net rent, being zero, meant that the
5% growth in net rent is impossible, for growth is the new rent
divided by the old rent, and anything divided by zero (other than
zero itself) is infinity.
|
DAN SULLIVAN
This
does make the numbers come out, as we shall see in Fred's new,
improved formulation.
|
Fred
Foldvary responds:
For example, at time T=1, r=100, t=.2, g=.05, i=.05
p=100/(.05+.2-.05)=100/.2=500 |
DAN SULLIVAN
Earlier,
[Fred Foldvary] said, "g is not a function of p. g is an
independent variable empirically observed, as is interest rate i."
That is false.
Both g and i are predictions to infinity as to what both rent
growth and interest rates will be, and therefore absurd on its
face, for nobody can state with confidence what either g or i will
be even in 10 years.
But if we are supposing, rather than predicting, we really should
be supposing based on something, and the growth in price is
predicated on an expected growth in net rents.
|
FRED FOLDVARY
In my
example of g=.05, p is empirically observed to be growing at 5%. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
No, you are predicting a 5% growth for the future, not observing
one from the past. But, we will pretend you can do that, so long
as your results are consistent.
|
FRED FOLVARY
One
year later, T=2, r=105, and p=105/.2=525 as both rent and price
have risen by 5%. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
But net rent is zero, and so is the growth in net rent zero.
Therefore, you are heading for error, as we shall see. |
FRED FOLDVARY
p and
r will keep growing at 5% until something changes. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
But net rent will be zero until something changes, according to
your equation. This will prove important, as there can be no
percentage growth in zero. |
FRED FOLDVARY
Now
let's move to 20 years later. At T=20
r=271; p=271/.2=1359
But suddenly and unexpectedly the rent stops growing. So far the
title holder has not actually gotten any rent payment, because all
the current rent was taxed. But the expectation was that someday,
if the rent stopped growing, then the title holder would get 20%
of the rent, and that would be a larger rent than the present-day
rent. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
You have contradicted yourself, in saying that
the rent stopped unexpectedly, but that the expectation was that
someday, if the rent stopped growing, then the title holder would
get 20% of the rent. Thus, the only way the land is worth
*anything* is if the rent stops growing. (If it slows growing, he
will get perhaps 10% of the rent, but that just muddies the
distinctions.) |
FRED FOLDVARY
So if
g falls to zero, then at T=20
p=271/(.05+.2)=271/.25= 1084.
The price falls from 1359 to 1084 because the growth of rent and
price are now zero. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
But the person who bought the land originally (or the one who
paid 1359) still made a sucker bet, because either the land would
never yeild rent or it would stop growing and collapse the price.
There is no other way. |
FRED FOLDVARY
The
percentage gain, after g falls to zero, is now
log(1084/500)/20=.039 or 3.9%. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
In other words, the person expecting a 5% return
paid about 20% too much, and/or was assessed about 20% too high.
Not coincidentally, Victor's assertion was that about 20% of the
rent would be left with the landholder, and a 20% assessment
reduction would accomplish that. |
FRED FOLDVARY
The
problem is, nobody knew when the rent and price would stop
growing. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
It doesn't matter, because there is no way the
return can come out right regardless of what year, as we shall see
from your 100 years example. |
FRED FOLDVARY
If
they knew it would stop growing in 20 years, the formula would not
be p=r/(i+t-g) but a present value only for the rents to be
received starting in 20 years. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
A better formulation (assuming your price
assessment, which will prove to have been too high) is to say that
the net rents are zero for 20 years and become $271 on the 21st
year and thereafter.
Thus, the total return after 20 years is $1084, minus the $500
originally invested, for a yeild of $584 profit. Had the person
paid $408, $1084 would have been a marginal return. Once again,
you are off by just under 20%. (This pattern should serve as a
hint.)
|
FRED FOLDVARY
So why
would someone pay for land at r/(i+t-g) if he is collecting no
rent and if when rent stops growing the percentage gain will be
less? Because nobody knows when the rent will stop growing, and
they expect the rent to keep growing indefinitely. Suppose it
grows for 100 years. Then r=14,841 p=74,207 when g becomes 0, then
p=59,365, with a growth rate of 4.77% |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
I don't know where you got those numbers. The
price, after 100 years of growth at 5%, should be $500 * 1.05^100,
which is 65,750, and the net rent to sustain such a price would
have to be 5% of that, or 3,287 per year. This means that, for the
capitalized value to have actually risen by 5%, the rent would
have to rise by 5.235%
If the rents rose 5%, as you are predicating, *gross* rent
becomes $13,150 per year, which is $100 * 1.05^100. The net rent
becomes $2630. The price, which is the rent divided by the
interest rate, becomes $52,600, or 80% of the return he could have
gotten by investing at the interest margin. |
DAN SULLIVAN
Suppose it grows for
100 years. Then r=14,841
p=74,207
when g becomes 0, then p=59,365, with a growth rate of 4.77%
|
Fred
Foldvary responds:
I don't know where you got those numbers. I'm using continuous
compounding: F=P*e^(it) it=5 since i=.05 and t=100 so
F=500*exp(1)^5 |
DAN SULLIVAN
The
price, after 100 years of growth at 5%, should be $500 * 1.05^100,
which is 65,750 |
Fred
Foldvary responds:
You are using annual compounding, where the rent
stays the same for a year and then suddenly jumps up 5%. I am
using continuous compounding where the rent grows continuously.
For one particular property, the landlord may raise the rent once
a year, but for a whole economy, the more likely case is that
rents are being increased at different times, and as whole they
rise continuously.
|
DAN SULLIVAN
In that case, the comparison is valid if you use the same
methodology to calculate the alternative return of 5% interest,
and you will still get the same errors. I just posted a formula
that has no such errors. I compounded annually for the rent growth
as well as for the comparative marginal investment, but I am sure
the end result would be the same if the compounding were
continuous in both cases.
|
FRED FOLDVARY
The price still falls
by the same percentage, but because of the long time period, the
compounding growth can be closer to 5%. Far enough into the
future, a small change in percentage growth becomes a large change
in the final amount. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
No, you did the math wrong somewhere. The return gets closer and
closer to 80%. By 100 years, it is so close that a little rounding
makes it 80% exactly. |
FRED FOLDVARY
So the further into the
future the growth continues, the closer to 5% will be the return
when the growth stops. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
Wrong. 4%
This seems to be what is happening with internet stocks. They
make no current profit, but are expected to keep growing rapidly.
But if growth stops in the near future, the return will not be so
high. So some of these stocks were priced unrealistically high, as
though growth would > continue forever. But it could not be
sustained, and that's why the stock values fell so much.
What is this, the greater-fool formula? |
DAN SULLIVAN
If there is no growth, the formula is easy. Price = net yield /
interest rate. or, Price = Rent - Tax / interest rate |
David
Hillary responds:
Once again it becomes necessary for me to demolish a vain attempt
to overturn the land value equation d=y-t+g.
...David Hillary's comments are continued below. |
DAN SULLIVAN
Here is a formula that
works, and is consistent at 1 year, at 20 years, at 100 years, and
at any year. But, by all means, let us think about what each part
of the formula is actually saying. ...
Let us use the numbers Fred used to get zero net rent. That is,
the interest rate is .05 the capitilzation rate, k, is therefore
20 |
Victor
Levis:
Only when the income stream is steady. Otherwise, use of this
term will confuse, and not illuminate. |
VICTOR LEVIS
Only when the income
stream is steady. Otherwise, use of this term will confuse, and
not illuminate. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
The original formula also depended on the income being steady. I
have been the most forthright of anyone in saying that no formula
can predict real life. However, the other formula was not working
even when the income stream *was* presumed to be steady. |
DAN SULLIVAN
The original formula
also depended on the income being steady. I have been the most
forthright of anyone in saying that no formula can predict real
life. However, the other formula was not working even when the
income stream *was* presumed to be steady.
|
Victor
Levis responds:
What I mean by 'steady', is that there is no growth at all. This
capitalization rate, or k, is not necessary in these formulae. It
only holds true in a special case. |
VICTOR LEVIS
What I mean by
'steady', is that there is no growth at all. This capitalization
rate, or k, is not necessary in these formulae. It only holds true
in a special case. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
The capitalization rate is nothing more than one over the
interest rate. It holds true in any hypothesis where the interest
rate holds true.
|
VICTOR LEVIS
If by capitalization
rate you mean the ratio of capitalized value to the income stream,
it is ONLY 'one over the interest rate' when the income stream is
steady. In the case of 4% growth in income stream, and 5% discount
rate, you agree below that the capitalization rate is 100 and not
20.
|
DAN SULLIVAN
The k constant in my
formula was simply the inverse of the discount rate or prevailing
interest rate. It was applied, in my formula, to the entire
return, which means growth value plus rent. Thus, it would still
be 20, but 20 * the entire yield, which is growth value plus rent,
no just rent. |
Victor
Levis responds:
Then we have just found your error. There is no
capitalization factor of 20. You need to do a Net Present Value on
each and every year's worth of net rent. The k=1/i only works if
the income stream never changes, and it is a convenient
shorthand-trick, not something to rely on in more complex cases.
I remember you saying something like "the entire yield is
$19.23 plus 5%" but that cannot be right, as that is only the
second year yield, and does not fully take into account the
permanent growth engendered by the 5% increase.
Only doing a separate NPV for each year takes everything into
account. |
DAN SULLIVAN
The growth rate, g, is
also .05,
which means the growth factor is 1.05
|
Victor
Levis responds:
Each and every year.
|
VICTOR LEVIS
Each and every year. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
According to the flawed formula, yes. I am only offering a
formula that is *mathematically* correct. |
DAN SULLIVAN
According to the flawed
formula, yes. I am only offering a formula that is
*mathematically* correct. |
Victor
Levis responds:
Accepted. Unfortunately, while I sympathize with what you are
trying to do, and especially in how you are trying to get David to
stop shouting at us and to finally recognize that no one will pay
$25,000 for a piece of land that carries no net rent, your formula
also goes wrong, but in a different place.
|
DAVID HILLARY
Once again it becomes
necessary for me to demolish a vain attempt to overturn the land
value equation d=y-t+g. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
Translation:
I AM THE GREAT AND POWERFUL WHIZZER OF ODDS. PAY
NO ATTENTION TO THE MAN BEHIND THE UNCERTAINTIES.
|
DAVID HILLARY
THIS
EQUATION IS CORRECT AND IT WORKS. OTHER PROPOSED EQUATIONS DO NOT
WORK UNLESS THEY ARE EQUIVILENT TO IT. THIS CAN BE DEMONSTRATED
WITH NUMERIC EXAMPLES. GIVE UP ON OVERTURNING IT.
|
DAVID HILLARY
R=$100
d=0.05
t=0.2
g=0.05
claimed P $403.85
Actual P $500
|
Dan
Sullivan responds:
"Actual P" is merely David's claimed P <
|
DAVID HILLARY
claimed P for period 21
$1 071.52
Claimed rate of P growth is 0.05 per period. i.e. price growth
equals rent growth.
|
Dan
Sullivan responds:
Is proportional, not equals, and it is actually proportional to
net rent growth. If net rent growth is zero, because net rent is
zero, then it doesn't matter what gross rent growth is. |
DAVID HILLARY
so P in year 2 is
going to be $424.04, a gain of $20.19.
Net rent is $100 less 0.2*$403.85 which is $19.23.
Total return to the investor is therefore $39.42. This 9.76% of
$403.85.
The rate of return should be d, which is 5%. |
DAVID HILLARY
Dan, your formula is defective, untrue and more complex that it
needs to be. d=y-t+g. This is the truth. I will show you.
R=$100
t=0.2
d=0.05
g=0.05
so we have P=$100/(0.05+0.02-0.05)=$500
Net rent is $100-$500*0.2=0, capital gain is 0.05*$500, which
gives a total return of 0.05*$500,which equates to a 5% rate of
return, like it should. There is only one Price-Rent ratio that
give a d rate of return in the form of the sum of the capital gain
and the net rent, and that is d+t-g. |
Dan
Sullivan:
David, I will go over my formula again, but your
formula is clearly wrong for net rent = 0 because there is no
actual return, now or ever, to the investor, so long as the
parameters of your formula are true. That is, you presume a growth
in price, when price is derivative of a growth in net rents, and
your scenario posits no growh in net rents.
When they are no longer true, everything must be readjusted, as
Fred has shown.
|
DAN SULLIVAN
The question becomes
how to define and calculate growth. Clearly, the growth that the
investor is looking for is a growth in net returns, not in price
per se, and certainly not in gross rent. After all, price is
derived from a projected growth in net returns, and not from
anything else. After all, we are trying to calculate actual value,
not the sucker-price.
|
DAN SULLIVAN
Let us presume that
the grand poobah of prediction has everyone rightly convinced that
rents will rise by 5% indefinitely, which just happens to be the
interest rate. Now let us logically construct a formula. |
DAN SULLIVAN
Price
is the capitalization of expected annual yield plus the
capitalization of expected growth in that yield. |
DAN SULLIVAN
Let us call k the
capitalization rate, which is the inverse of the interest rate.
Thus, if the interest rate is .05, k is 20. Not a big deal; it
just saves repetition of a step.
Thus, P = k*(r-t+g)
Except that, first of all, the tax is a portion of the price, and
not just a number. Hence it is cleaner to write,
P = k*(r-tP+g)
|
DAN SULLIVAN
But what is g? If it
is not a growth in the net yield, then it is irrelevant to the
investor, or to the future investors on whom he will attempt to
unload the property. The better expression to capture g, then, is
to say it is a factor of r-tP.
Thus we have, P = k *[(r-tP)+ g(r-tP)] That is,
Price = K * [(rent-tax on price)+growth(rent-tax on price)]
Factoring out the r-tP, we get,
P = K [(1+g)(r-tP))
|
DAN SULLIVAN
Now, the nature of
growth, or compounded interest, is that you don't deal with the
interest alone, but you multiply the principle by itself with
interest each year. That is, if something has a 5% growth rate,
what actually compounds is the value itself, which becomes 1.05
times the prior value. So, above, "1+g" is actually a
more cogent number than g itself. |
DAN SULLIVAN
To elaborate, rather
than saying something gains 5% interest each year, it is
mathematically cleaner, and less prone to error, to say that it
multiplies by 1.05. Indeed, the erroneous formula was adding
growth, with no sense of growth to *what*. Growth is a multiplying
effect, and so it is much better to have a new number G, which is
(1+g). This also helps with negative interest, as G is still
positive.
Just keeping things simple so the "tyros" won't get
confused. :^)
P = k*G(r-tP) |
DAN SULLIVAN
I
see the tax is a function of the price, which means we have price
on both sides of the equation. Not good, but that is one reason
assessing the tax against the price is not such a good idea.
Anyhow, it is easy enough to fix after numbers are plugged in. ... |
DAN SULLIVAN
Let us use the numbers
Fred used to get zero net rent.
That is,
the interest rate is .05
the capitalization rate, k, is therefore 20
The growth rate, g, is also .05,
which means the growth factor is 1.05
|
Victor
Levis responds:
Only when the income stream is steady. Otherwise, use of this
term will confuse, and not illuminate.
|
DAN SULLIVAN
The initial rent is
$100. |
Victor
Levis responds:
OK |
DAN SULLIVAN
... the tax rate is 20%
of the price, or .2; the tax itself is .2P |
Victor
Levis responds:
OK. Or more precisely .2 of assessed value. |
VICTOR LEVIS
OK. Or more precisely,
.2 of assessed value. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
No, it's .2 of market value. It could be .4 of assessed value, if
the assessment is half the market value.
|
DAN SULLIVAN
No, it's .2 of market
value. It could be .4 of assessed value, if the assessment is half
the market value. |
Victor
Levis responds:
Whatever. The fact is, it's based on an assessment, and all of
you are only ASSUMING that the assessment has a firm connection to
the price. The investor does not really care about anything except
the expected tax value in dollars for each year. |
VICTOR LEVIS
Whatever. The fact is,
it's based on an assessment, and all of you are only ASSUMING that
the assessment has a firm connection to the price. The investor
does not really care about anything except the expected tax value
in dollars for each year. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
These formulas are all about assuming what cannot
be assumed. However, the effect of tax collection on value derives
from the tax as a percentage of the *actual* value. That is, if
they officially assess at 100% but in fact assess this property at
80%, then a 25% tax on paper is a 20% tax in fact. In any case,
the formula depends on the tax in fact, and assumes that ratio of
the assessment to market value will, like everything else in the
formula, remain constant. |
DAN SULLIVAN
These formulas are all
about assuming what cannot be assumed. However, the effect of tax
collection on value derives from the tax as a percentage of the
*actual* value. That is, if they officially assess at 100% but in
fact assess this property at 80%, then a 25% tax on paper is a 20%
tax in fact. In any case, the formula depends on the tax in fact,
and assumes that ratio of the assessment to market value will,
like everything else in the formula, remain constant. |
Victor
Levis responds:
Let me repeat MY calculation for growth of 4% annually with a
discount rate of 5%.
|
VICTOR LEVIS
Let me repeat MY
calculation for growth of 4% annually with a discount rate of 5%. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
Sure. Now that we are not dividing by zero, it is a
mathematically realistic scenario. (However, it still yields an
unrealistically low ratio of rent to price, and so I think 4%
growth in rents is well beyond reality.)
|
VICTOR LEVIS
Let me repeat MY
calculation for growth of 4% annually with a discount rate of 5%.
Show me ANY flaw with its determination of the land's market
value. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
For the value to be a normal investment value, it has to promise
a normal return, which is the combination rent and growth.
|
DAN SULLIVAN
For the value to be a
normal investment value, it has to promise a normal return, which
is the combination rent and growth.
|
Victor
Levis responds:
Agreed. Unfortunately, you didn't calculate the growth correctly.
|
VICTOR LEVIS
Agreed. Unfortunately,
you didn't calculate the growth correctly. |
Dan
Sullivan responds:
Probably not. Did you try it with numbers from a valid scenario?
I was just wondering if my formula was shown to be invalid for the
same reason that David's was. |
DAN SULLIVAN
To be more precise,
the combined return left to the investor from net rent plus growth
of net rent will be exactly 80% of the price, and the bulk of that
will be rent itself. |
DAN SULLIVAN
Now to solve.
P = k * G * (r-tP) = 20 * 1.05 * ($100-.2P)
= 21 * ($100 - .2P)
P = $2100 - 4.2P
5.2P = $2100
P = 403.85 |
Victor
Levis responds:
I'll check your result and see if that makes sense. |
DAN SULLIAN
Now that we have solved
for P, let us see how the numbers play out in year one, year 20,
and year 100.
Year one.
Rent = 100
Price = $403.
Tax = .2P = $80.77
Net rent = $19.23
Growthfactor = 1.05* net rent = $20.19 |
Victor
Levis responds:
What is this 'growth' you are talking about? |
DAN SULLIVAN
That is, rent plus
growth = $20.19
That just happens to be exactly 5% of the price. |
Victor
Levis responds:
It also just happens to be a meaningless figure. Well, not
completely meaningless. It is the net rent of year 2. But just
year 2. In year 3 it goes higher still. And so forth. |
VICTOR LEVIS
The way I understand
it, it is this:
In year one, the net rent is $19.23, because the assessor has
valued the property at $403.85 and the council has levied a tax of
20%, thus hitting the landowner with $80.77 of tax against $100 of
rent. |
VICTOR LEVIS
In year 2, the net
rent will go up by 5%, because the gross rent will go up by 5%,
and so will the assessment.
Therefore, in year 2, the net rent will be $20.19.
In year 3, the net rent will be $21.20. |
VICTOR LEVIS
What
is the net present value of the whole stream?
It is the sum of the net present values of each individual year.
The year one NPV, assuming the tax is paid at the end of the
year, the same time as the rent is received, is $19.23 divided by
1.05 equaling $18.31.
The year two NPV is $20.19 divided by 1.05 divided by 1.05 again,
which is $18.31 again. |
VICTOR LEVIS
If you do the math, you
will find that the NPV is $18.31 each and every year, and so the
sum of the NPV's is.........infinite.
That's right. Infinite. The assessors have under-assessed.
|
David
Hillary responds:
Remember that an increase in valuation will increase the tax and
therefore reduce the net rent, which means an increase in
valuation (in terms of Price Rent ratio) will ultimately eliminate
the infinite value. |
DAVID HILLARY
Remember that an
increase in valuation will increase the tax and therefore reduce
the net rent, which means an increase in valuation (in terms of
Price Rent ratio) will ultimately eliminate the infinite value. |
Victor
Levis:
Yes, I did assume that Dan was doing the Assessing, and
increasing the assessment by 5% each year. :-) |
VICTOR LEVIS
Which is why the discount rate for land cannot be permanently
equal to or less than the expected growth rate in rent. |
David
Hillary responds:
You have proved that the assessment is incorrect.
Dan's like that, he just can't figure out how to do valuations of
income streams properly. You are correct to say that at $403 or
whatever Dan give is under-assessed. The correct value is $500.
You are incorrect to say that the rent growth rate cannot equal
the discount rate perpetually. In Singapore the real economic
growth rate averages around 6-7% and the real interest rate is
between 1 and 2%. |
DAVID HILLARY
Current estimated
sustainable economic growth rates in rich capitalist countries are
about equal to or in excess of the world real interest rate and
their own domestic interest rate. If taxation and public pensions
were reduced or eliminated growth would be higher and savings
would be higher and the interest rate might be even lower. Rent
seems to be directly connected to overall economic activity and
rent growth and economic growth will be very similar to each
other. |
DAVID HILLARY
The solow growth model
indicates that the economic growth will always equal the interest
rate if the consumption maximising savings rate occurs. There is
no reason to think that d cannot equal g on an ongoing basis. |
VICTOR LEVIS
Which is why the
discount rate for land cannot be permanently equal to or less than
the expected growth rate in rent. You have proved that the
assessment is incorrect. Dan's like that, he just can't figure out
how to do valuations of income streams properly. You are correct
to say that at $403 or whatever Dan give is under-assessed. The
correct value is $500. If the tax takes all the rent, and is
expected to do so forever, then Fred and I are right, the private
value is 0. The public value, the value to the community as a
whole, since it owns all the rent, will be finite only if the
expected growth in rent is less than the discount rate. |
David
Hillary responds:
From what I could gather Fred thinks the private value is $500,
as I did. |
DAVID HILLARY
From what I could
gather Fred thinks the private value is $500, as I did. |
Victor
Levis responds:
But he specifically stated that this was because
it was not expected for rent to rise indefinitely. This is the
statement we are waiting for you to make, as well. |
VICTOR LEVIS
You are incorrect to say that the rent growth rate cannot equal
the discount rate perpetually. In Singapore the real economic
growth rate averages around 6-7% and the real interest rate is
between 1 and 2%.
So, do people pay INFINITE amounts to buy the tiniest piece of
land? Or do they pay finite amounts?
If they pay finite amounts, then Fred is probably right, and land
investors do NOT believe that the their land rent will grow 6-7%
every year, indefinitely, no matter what YOU believe or say is
'sustainable'.
In fact, I don't understand why you haven't put every single
dollar you own into buying Singapore real estate.
Let me give you a clue into what may be astray in your analysis.
You started the above paragraph saying that I am wrong about the
rent growth rate, but ended it with an empirical observation of
economic growth, not rent growth.
As I said the other day, I retract by statement that economic
growth cannot exceed the discount rate. It can, so long as this
growth is not capital-dependent. But if and when such a phenomenon
ever exists, despite the assumptions of the Solow model, rent is
not in fact expected to increase by as much as the overall
economy. |
David
Hillary responds:
ok we have four variables here:
i the interest rate in the econony (net marginal product of
capital in SGM)
d the discount rate on land, equal to i plus p, the risk premium
on land, which depends on how risky the land asset is. (I have
modelled the risk premium in my macro-model as being proportional
to the sensitivity of the land value to the change in d-g)
g the rent growth rate
the other variable is the growth of output. I have used assumed
that rent is a fixed fraction of output, based on the use of a
form of Cobb-Douglas production function (Y=th*L^a*K^b*N^(1-a-b)
where th is technology, L is the labour force employed, K is the
capital stock and N is the stock of land (fixed). a and b are
constants. Factor incomes are their marginal products giving
labour a*Y, capital b*Y and land the remainder. Given the
difficulty in measuring factor shares because of indirect taxes
and the business cycle and so on, it seems that the wage share of
output does go up and down over time. However the Cobb-Douglas
production function was created on the basis that in the long term
the factor shares seemed to be unchanged over long periods of
time. I think that for the type of modelling we are doing this
approach is the best available and that treating rent as a fixed
share of output is sensible and believable, despite being a
simplification of reality. More advanced modelling of land
endowment and use could yield different results, but i suspect it
would raise very substantial difficulties in using for the
aggregate valuation of land and the effect of land value tax on
land value. |
|