Our Unsound Tax Laws
and Measures for Reform
Robert de Fremery
[Reprinted from The Commercial and Financial
Chronicle, 7 July, 1960]
Opposed to any taxation
of privately created values, Mr. de Fremery strongly favors
reforming our tax laws so that only publicly created land rental
value would be taxed. The author joins a list of advocates and
forerunners of the Henry George single tax plan which he cites;
raises and answers arguments against the taxation of the annual
rental value of land; and goes on to specify the many advantages of
his proposal. Mr. de Fremery claims that: Henry George's principles
have never been refuted; there would be no need for any other taxes
so long as Government costs are correlated to this single source of
tax revenue; such a tax cannot be shifted; and this offers the best
protection for private property and free enterprise.
Daniel Webster once said: "A free government cannot long
endure where the tendency of the laws is to concentrate the wealth of
the country in the hands of a few, and to render the masses poor and
dependent." An objective analysis of the tax laws used in
most countries will, I believe, lead any fair-minded person to the
conclusion that these laws do just that. They tend to concentrate
wealth in the hands of a privileged few - taking from those who
produce and giving to those who do not.[1]
The basic defect in our tax system is that we allow our local, state,
and Federal governments to tax away privately created values
while at the same time an enormous amount of publicly created
value remains in private hands.
Many are surprised to hear of publicly created value as distinct from
privately created values. Victims of unjust taxation all their lives,
they are shocked by the suggestion that it is possible to have an
essentially burdenless tax system - that there is a natural reservoir
of publicly created value, over and above all privately created
values, which could pay for all legitimate activities of
government. Yet many economists have recognized this fact for more
than 200 years. And although we draw to some extent upon this source
of revenue, the extent to which we do not is responsible for many of
our economic ills today.
The difference between publicly created and privately created values,
once seen, is never forgotten. Both result from the competitive
bidding within society for the right to consume or use something. But
it is of utmost significance that privately created values result from
competitive bidding for goods and services produced by man, whereas
publicly created values result from competitive bidding for something
no man produced - the land upon which we live and work and
whose value increases as the community in which it is located grows.
In the one case men are bidding for goods and services produced by
each other as private individuals. In the other men are bidding for
the important right to use part of the earth's surface. In the one
case you have privately created values. In the other you have a
publicly created value.
Distinguishes Improvements' From Land Rental Value
It is necessary, of course, to distinguish between the publicly
created value of a piece of land and the value of improvements made by
the landholder. A person may improve his land with his own money and
effort by landscaping, planting crops, building a house or factory or
other structure. Such improvements are privately created values. And
when we speak of the publicly created value of a parcel of land, we
are specifically excluding the value of any privately financed
improvement in or on it.
As each community grows, both publicly created and privately created
values grow with it. Privately created values increase as an expanding
population produces more houses, more food, more manufactured products
and more services. But this same activity together with the activities
of Local, state, and Federal governments causes an increase in the
value of land over and above the total of all privately created
values. For example, before Rockefeller Center could be erected, the
bare land under it had to be leased from its owners. The rent agreed
upon for this piece of bare land was $3.5 million a year, a sum which
is still being paid each year to its title-holders. Bare land in that
location is worth that much to those who need to use it. Similar
examples of the high rental value of land, apart from any improvements
in or on it, can be found in every large city.
The increasing value of land resulting from the growth of each
community is in no sense created by the productive effort of each
titleholder. The land that is most favorably situated will have the
highest value regardless of who holds title to it. Thus a man who
contributes nothing to the community in which he lives -
a man who produces nothing and performs no useful service to
society -may, nevertheless, have a steadily increasing income
because he holds title to a piece of land in the center of a growing
city. The rental value of his land will steadily increase as the
community grows. That is what is meant by a publicly created value. It
is created by the community as a whole and exists independently of the
productive activity of the landholder.
Stresses Basic Differences
The problems we have in taxation today result primarily from our
failure to take advantage of this basic difference between the
publicly created value of land and privately created values of goods
and services. We quite foolishly allow taxes to fall indiscriminately
on both publicly created and privately created values. Privately
created values should be sacredly protected as private property free
of all taxes so as to encourage the maximum production of wealth. On
the other hand the publicly created rental value of land - which no
individual can rightfully claim as his alone because the public as a
whole created it-should be looked upon as legitimate public property
that, ideally, ought to be recovered by the community through taxation
and used for public purposes. To the extent this is done a just
revenue is derived that make it unnecessary to levy taxes on privately
created values.
Years of experience by assessors throughout the United States and in
many other parts of the world have demonstrated that the publicly
created value of land is readily separable from the value of private
property in improvements. But if, in some cases, it is difficult to
distinguish between publicly created and privately created values -
between what is rightfully public property and what is rightfully
private property - it is still inexcusable not to make the effort to
do so. We cannot make secure to the individual what belongs to him
until we make secure to the public what belongs to it. We cannot
preserve a system of private property unless we make ell levels of
government draw revenue solely from what is legitimately public
property.
Depicts Disadvantages of Present Tax System
Consider the disastrous consequences of not securing public revenue
from the proper source:
(1) By failing to make full use of the publicly created value of land
for public purposes, we have forced local, state, and Federal
governments to obtain more and more revenue from privately created
values. That means sales taxes, income taxes, taxes on our homes,
factories, machinery, cigarettes, gasoline, and all the other sources
from which governments try to raise revenue today. Such taxes
discourage the production of wealth and add to inflationary forces by
increasing costs of production.
(2) By allowing a large part of the publicly created rental value of
land to be privately pocketed, we encourage speculation in land. Vast
amounts of excellent land in both city and country lie either
underdeveloped or completely idle, the taxes being too low to induce
the holders to put it to better use or sell it to those who will. The
enormously inflated prices of land today are due to this cause and
stand as a major roadblock to the construction industry. Thus, me
June, 1958 issue of
House & Home (leading magazine for the construction
industry) editorialized as follows:
"It just plain is not true that land for home
building is getting scarce. What is true is that land speculators
are making land scarce by holding millions of acres off the market
to get higher prices (or pricing those acres out of today's market,
which is the same thing in different words) ...
"The one best way to stop land price inflation and perhaps
squeeze out some of the past inflation is to get together and fight
to put more of the tax load on land and less of the tax load on
improvements. This shift might make it too costly for speculators to
hold good home sites idle hoping to squeeze us for still higher
prices later on. "Higher taxes on land would hurt no one but
the land speculators. Higher taxes on land would permit lower taxes
on houses and other improvements. Higher taxes on land are the only
taxes that would stimulate production instead of discouraging it.
"Our industry has to live closer to the land speculator than
any other industry. We have a closer view of the harm land
speculation is doing our economy, so we should be first to tell the
tax planners and the , tax collectors that higher land taxes are the
one way to raise more revenue without hurting anyone except our
public enemy No. 1."
Of course, the real culprit - our real public enemy - is not the land
speculator but rather a tax system that encourages speculation in
land. The public as a whole is responsible for its own misfortune by
not insisting that the publicly created value of land be used as the
source of public revenue.
(3) When we deprive our citizens of the full reward for their
productive activities by levying taxes on the things they buy, the
homes they build, and the money they earn, a growing number of them
will be unable to afford decent housing. Slums are an inevitable
result. By taking taxes off income, sales, and houses and putting them
on the publicly created value of land, lower income groups will be
more able to afford decent housing, and slumlords will be obliged to
erect decent housing in order to pay their taxes.
(4) When governments have the power - as they do today - o tax
privately created values and spend the money on public improvements
that add value to nearby land, it is inevitable that powerful lobbies
representing these landholders will exert pressure to pass pork barrel
legislation. On the state and Federal levels these lobbies strive to
increase government spending for highways, dams, schools, etc.,
because no state or Federal revenue comes from taxes on land. Locally
these lobbies are engaged in holding down property taxes which fall on
their lands while boosting sales taxes and any other taxes that will
substitute for taxes on their landholdings. The result is an inherent
tendency for the state and Federal governments to spend themselves
into bankruptcy while local governments claim they are impoverished.
(5) The combination of the above factors results in a natural
tendency toward a loss of local responsibility and a growing
dependence of local governments on central government - a trend that
threatens the survival of free institutions as our forefathers knew
them.
Criticizes Educational System That Ignores Henry George
The peculiar nature of land value and its suitability as a source of
public revenue has been recognized by many economists during the past
200 years. Adam Smith distinguished between
ground rent and ordinary rent for the use of
improvements. He said ground rent was a superior source of public
revenue because taxes obtained from this source had no harmful effect
on enterprise. John Stuart Mill referred to the rising value of land
resulting from the growth of a community as an "unearned
increment" if allowed to remain in the hands of landholders.
During the last half of the 19th Century, several scholars - each
independently of the others - discovered this natural source of
government revenue - this fund of publicly created value that makes it
possible to have a burdenless tax system. But the man who did more
than any other before him to clarify the distinctive nature of land
value, and who thereby incurred the wrath of powerful landholding
interests, was the United States economist and social philosopher,
Henry George. No man in the last 100 years has received more abuse and
been so grossly misrepresented. Yet he succeeded in winning the
acclaim of statesmen, philosophers, economists, and leading citizens
all over the world.
Henry George was a man of intense faith. He firmly believed in a
moral order and in the beneficence of natural laws. He saw clearly
that the value of land is the natural source of public revenue because
not only is it a publicly created value over and above all privately
created values but it grows as the need /or public revenue grows.
And he realized the awful truth that because the value of land grows
as each community grows, a blight will fall on any community in direct
proportion to its refusal to obey natural law by obtaining its,
revenue from this source. He saw that to the extent publicly created
values are privately pocketed, a relatively few landholders become
wealthy while the vast majority of people are kept relatively poor
under a crushing burden of direct and indirect taxes on their
productive activity. He saw that if a government robs the people of
the fruit of their efforts while at the same time giving a favored few
values to which they are not entitled, the moral fibre of both groups
will be destroyed. The basic principles so ably espoused by Henry
George have been endorsed by Leo Tolstoy, Woodrow Wilson, David Lloyd
George, Henry Ford, John Dewey, Albert Einstein, Winston Churchill,
Theodore Roosevelt, Albert Jay Nock, Rabbi Stephen S. Wise, Sun Yat
Sen, Louis D. Brandeis, Clarence Darrow, Irving Fisher, John R.
Commons, Samuel Gompers, and many others. But the sad fact is that few
high school or college graduates have heard either of him or of the
clear and just principles he sought to popularize - principles
which have never been refuted. Commenting on this neglect, Tolstoy
said:
"The chief weapon against the teaching of Henry
George was that which is always used against irrefutable and
self-evident truths. This method, which is still being applied in
relation to George, was that of hushing up."
Economists' Views Yesterday And Currently
Largely as a result of Henry George's influence on economic thought,
the American Economic Association had a round table discussion of land
value taxation at its annual meeting in 1907. The final canvass of
opinion showed that an overwhelming majority of those present agreed
on the soundness of the following three propositions:
(1) The site value of land is a creation of the community, not a
creation of the landholder.
(2) A tax levied on the site value of land cannot be shifted nor
recovered from the tenant by raising his rent.
(3) A tax levied on the site value of land is burdenless. The
community, in taxing site value, is merely recovering a value it has
created.
That was over 50 years ago. Recently, Dr. Glenn E. Hoover, past
President of the Pacific Coast Economic Association, observed that
most economists today maintain the same position.
Many prominent statesmen during and after Henry George's life
recognized the validity of his teaching. Notable among these were
Winston Chrurchill and Theodore Roosevelt. Mr. Churchill gave two
brilliant speeches attacking land monopoly - one in the House of
Commons, the other in Edinburgh. In the Edinburgh speech, Churchill
said:
"I hope you will understand that, when I speak of
the land monopolist, I am dealing more with the process than with
the individual landowner. I have no wish to hold any class up to
public disapprobation. I do not think, that the man who makes money
by unearned increment in land is morally a worse man than anyone
else who gathers his profit where he finds it in this hard world
under the law and according to common usage. It is not the
individual I attack, it is the system. It is not the man who is bad,
it is the law which is bad. It is not the man who is blameworthy for
doing what the law allows and what other men do; it is the State
which would be blameworthy were it not to endeavour to reform the
law and correct the practice. We do not want to punish the landlord.
We want to alter the law."
Churchill never, retracted any of these statements. Quite to the
contrary, they were verified and confirmed by inclusion in a volume, "Liberalism
and the Social Problem," which he later made public. In the
preface to that work he wrote:
"The opinions and arguments are unaltered and hereby
confirmed, and I press them earnestly and insistently upon the
public."
Taunted recently in the House of Commons with once having "sung
the land song," he retorted, "I shall sing it again."
Theodore Roosevelt, in a speech delivered Aug. 6, 1912, showed his
grasp of the subject:
"Alaska should be developed at once, but in the
interest of the actual settler. The government should keep the fee
of all of the coal fields and allow them to be operated by lessees,,
with the condition in the lease that nonuse shall operate as a
forfeit. Moreover, it would be well in Alaska to try a system of
land taxation which will, so far as possible, remove all the burdens
from those who actually use the land, whether for building or for
agricultural purposes, and will operate against any man who holds
the land for speculation or derives an income from it based, not on
his own exertions, but on the increase in value due to activities
not his own."
"Why," one may ask, "hasn't the world made better use
of sound tax principles if economists and leading statesmen have
recognized their validity?"
Local governments in the United States - through the property tax --
have made some use of land value as a source of revenue. But there has
been a great change since World War I. The percentage of total public
revenues coming from land has steadily declined since that time -
partly because of the burdensomeness of that part of the property tax
that falls on improvements and personal property, and partly because
of the enormous political influence of landed interests which always
look to the state and Federal governments or to local nonproperty
taxes for substitute funds that should be raised by local taxes on the
rental value of land.
Countries That Are Taxing Land
Some areas of the world, notably Australia, New Zealand, and Denmark,
have made good use of sound tax principles by perfecting the property
tax. Instead of allowing this tax to fall on both land and
improvements, they have removed, or are in the process of removing,
all taxes on improvements and putting the full burden of this tax on
land, where it belongs. The resulting stimulus to the construction
industry is always apparent. Higher taxes on land induce land
speculators to sell their idle holdings, thus making land available to
builders. The removal of taxes from buildings obviously encourages
construction.
But although these countries have made progress in the right
direction by removing taxes on improvements, they still have a long
way to go. There are still many taxes falling on privately created
values while an enormous amount of publicly created land value remains
in private hands.
The high price of bare land is proof of this fact.
Progress in the direction of a completely sound revenue system will
follow readily once the public thoroughly understands the subject. The
reason the public doesn't understand taxation is that the basic
principles have been woefully misrepresented by powerful privileged
interests. For example, it is claimed these principles threaten our
system of private property. Exactly the opposite is true. These
principles assert an absolute, unqualified property right in all that
a man's enterprise, ingenuity and exertion enable him to produce. If
you build a house, or raise a herd of cattle, or work for a weekly pay
check, it should be yours completely and absolutely. Your ownership
should not be required to meet any conditions imposed by a tax
collector. There should be no income tax, no corporation tax, no tax
on buildings or machinery, no tax on trade, no sales tax. As Henry
George puts it:
"Instead of weakening and confusing the idea of
property, I would surround it with stronger sanctions. Instead of
lessening the incentive to the production of wealth, I would make it
more powerful by making the reward more certain.
No matter how
many millions any man can get by methods which do not involve the
robbery of others - they are his; let him have them."
Taxed Property Is Not Private Property
Another bogeyman is the question of who would own the land if all
revenue came from land values. Here again some have become confused
over the meaning of private property. To the extent that property is
taxed, it ceases to be private. What a man creates or earns can be
considered as truly private property only if it is his to do with as
he sees fit - free of any taxes levied upon it. Private property must
therefore be understood as
property that is not subject to taxation. Since taxes should
fall solely on publicly created 'land values, it is correct to say
that land should not be classified as private property in this sense.
But bear in mind we do not have this kind of private property in land
today, nor do we have private property in anything! Taxes fall on our
land, our homes, our incomes, our purchases, our inheritances. That's
just what we should object to. Public revenue should come solely from
the publicly created value of land. We should hold as private
property, tax-free, all privately created values. How else can we
encourage the production of wealth? Let our land - which should be
looked upon as our common heritage - continue to be privately held,
but require each landholder to pay into the public treasury the
publicly created rental value of the land he holds. Justice demands no
less. Then, and then only, will it be possible to protect privately
created values by freeing them of taxes.
Sees It Lessening: Government Power
The question is sometimes asked: Doesn't land value taxation place
too much power in the hands of government? No. It has the opposite
Effect. Modern governments are dangerous because we have given them
the power to take privately created values away from us. When we allow
our governments to deprive us of the fruits of our labors, we impair
our ability to fend for ourselves. Many of us are forced to become
wards of the state. The only effective way to limit the power of
government and to make certain it remains our servant is to deny it
the power to deprive a man of the fruit of his effort. We should
compel all levels of government to live within their legitimate
income, the publicly created value of land, the amount people are
willing to pay for exclusive use of the land they hold. Governments
are not entitled to more than this. And it is particularly wrong for
any government to deprive any citizen of privately created values -
which is now being done on a grand scale - as long as a single dollar
of publicly created value remains in private hands.
Curiously enough, the reverse of the above question is sometimes used
as an argument against sound tax reform. It is claimed that the
proposed system of taxation would weaken the government unduly and
place it in the embarrassing position of being unable to make both
ends meet. There are several answers to this. First, if our
governments ho longer took from us the values we create as
individuals, we would no longer have to be taken care of by our
government to the extent we are today. Second, when we secure public
revenue from the proper source, we have less "pork barrel"
legislation. Landholders become watchdogs of the public purse rather
than pressure groups asking for more spending for highways, dams, and
irrigation projects that will increase the value of their
land-holdings without their having to pay for it. Third, when taxes
are removed from improvements or other privately created values, the
demand for land naturally increases. People will pay more for the
exclusive use of land which they can improve without being taxed for
the improvement. Thus the public revenue from land values rises as
other taxes are removed.
It may still be argued, however, that our various levels of
government may want more income than they can get from the annual
rental value of land. Maybe they will. But that is no excuse for
allowing them to leave a large! part of their legitimate revenue in
private hands today. If, after our tax system is put on a sound basis,
our governments still do not have sufficient revenue to make both ends
meet, then there is reason to believe we should cut down the size of
our government. We must resist the attempt of governments to
confiscate privately created values. There is no other way to respect
the right to private property - the foundation of our free enterprise
system.
Claims Landowner Would Be Freer Than He Is Today
Another common misunderstanding is that somehow a thorough going
system of land value taxation would mean that the government rather
than private individuals would have the power to allocate sites as a
consequence of which we would all be subservient to the government.
But that is not the case. It would still be up to the market place to
determine the use to which land is put. There would still be a free
market in land. Titles to land would still be exchanged - but at
greatly reduced prices. Each landholder would be just as free as he is
today to put his land to its best use. As a matter of fact, he would
be much more free than he is today because the amount of taxes he pays
will be independent of the improvements he puts on his land. He will
no longer be taxed for improving his land.
Some landholders misjudge the effect of tax reform. They don't
realize how much they stand to gain from a sound tax system. The
higher taxes we would pay on the land we hold would be more than
offset by the elimination of taxes on improvements and personal
property, of income and sales taxes, and the huge burden of indirect
taxes hidden in the price of goods and services purchased. The only
sufferers from this reform will be the relatively few speculators in
underdeveloped land or those whose income comes primarily from ground
rent rather than from the rendering of a useful service to society.
Surely it should not be difficult for those who wish to preserve our
free enterprise system to decide whether or not we should continue
protecting the special interests of this small segment of the
population at the expense of everyone who is engaged in useful
productive activity. Surely we have the wisdom to stop this senseless
taxation of privately created values when there is an ample supply of
publicly created value that can be used to support our local, state,
and Federal governments.
Another stumbling block that prevents some people from accepting
sound tax reform is their belief that if taxes on the value of land
are increased, a landholder who has invested in land so as to have the
privilege of pocketing funds obtained by leasing the land to others
should be compensated by the government when he loses this privilege.
But why should anybody be compensated just because the government
changes its source of revenue? Was anybody compensated when the income
tax was put into effect? Of course not. The whole idea of compensation
is absurd. All taxation, no matter where it falls, involves the
confiscation of value. No matter where the government gets its
revenue, confiscation of value takes place. The government takes
values that are privately held and puts them to use for public
purposes. It is absurd, therefore, to compensate the landholder just
because taxes on the publicly created value of his land are increased.
As a matter of fact, if anybody deserves compensation, it is all those
who have been robbed of their privately created values under the
existing tax system, not those who have been permitted to pocket the
publicly created value of land all these years. But if we are wise, we
will not try to correct past injustices. We will simply insist that
justice be done from now on.
Finds Single Tax to Be Most Equitable
Another variation of the above argument is the claim that it would be
wrong to obtain all public revenue from landholders when a large
number of citizens have no land. But those who have no land are paying
ground rent to those who do. In other words landless people provide
landholders with the money to pay taxes falling on their land. And if
we bear in mind the essential difference between publicly created and
privately created values, we are forced to the conclusion that taxes
on the publicly created rental value of land are the only taxes that
are absolutely equitable to all citizens. This is so because the
annual rental value of land, being a publicly created value,
legitimately belongs to all, share and share alike. Theoretically, our
government should recover the total rental value of land - our common
heritage -and divide it equally among all citizens. But since our
governments need revenue and we wish to avoid having taxes levied on
privately created values, it makes sense for each citizen to assign to
his local government his equal share of this public value. By so doing
he contributes the same as every other citizen to the cost of
government. Certainly there is no other source of revenue as equitable
as this.
Denies Tax Can Be Shifted
At the opposite extreme of the claim that land value taxation is
wrong because landholders would be the only ones paying taxes is the
claim that landholders would be paying no taxes at all. It is claimed
that they would merely raise their rents in proportion to the increase
in taxes falling on their lands. But this is one thing all reputable
economists agree can not be done. If site A (land only) in the heart
of a city is worth $1,000 per month to whoever uses it, while site B
(land only) on the outskirts of the city is worth only $100.00 per
month, then site A is worth only $900.00 more per month than is site
B. A change in the amount of taxes falling on these two landholders
cannot affect the relative value of these sites. Suppose, for example,
that an attempt were made to get $2,000 and $200.00 per month
respectively for these two sites just because each landholder were
required to pay taxes of $1,000 and $100.00 respectively to the city.
Obviously, the tenants in site A would move to lower cost land. Site A
is not worth $1,800 more per month than site B. If it were, the
landholder would be getting it in today's market.
Although a tax on land values affects the price of land, it cannot
affect its rental value. There is no disagreement among professional
economists on this point.
Explains Mechanics of Tax Collection
The question naturally arises: How should Federal, state, and local
governments obtain the rental value of land? The practical answer is
that we should return to the constitutional provision that requires
our Federal government to apportion direct land taxes among the states
according to their respective populations. The states, in turn, should
obtain this revenue and the revenue for their own support by
apportionment among their counties, in the way Nebraska, Texas,
Montana, and a number of other states still do. The counties, as
agents of the states, should collect their revenue, and the revenue
needed by state and Federal governments, from the rental value of
their lands, using existing property tax collection machinery. These
changes would reverse the trend of the last 50 years. Instead of lower
levels of government becoming increasingly dependent upon higher
levels of government for aid, thereby losing their independence, the
higher levels of government would return to dependence upon the lower.
That is as it should be if we wish to preserve our liberties.
Some may claim, "It's too late to change the rules of the game."
But if a person has a clear understanding of the disastrous effect
that some of the existing rules are having upon us-he will realize the
wisdom of making the rules sounder so as to protect each person's
right to enjoy the fruits of his efforts. The first barrier to the
spread of Communism is a tax system that differentiates between
publicly created and privately created values. Then and only then can
all privately created values be treated as private property, secure in
private hands, immune from confiscation by tax collectors.
In his book, "Constructive Taxation for Free Enterprise,"
Judge John R. Fuchs stated the issue clearly as follows:
"There can be no hope of peace and order in society
without a clear recognition of what is public and what is private
property. The soundness of the very foundation of society depends
upon this.
We must distinguish between what is Mine, Thine,
and Ours."
Almost two thousand years ago, a famous teacher of Nazareth stated
the same basic principle when he said: "Render unto Caesar
that which is Caesar's." Truly, there is nothing new under
the sun. We may have a new set of faces. But our problems are the
same. We cannot escape the consequences of our immoral acts. We cannot
hope to achieve the kind of life our Creator intended for us until we
provide ourselves with a sound and just method of raising public
revenue, and a sound monetary system.
NOTES
- The same can be said of our
banking laws. See the author's "Banking and Monetary Reforms
to Preserve Private Enterprise," The Commercial and
Financial Chronicle, June 7, 1956, p. 13, and "Our
Unsound Monetary System and Measures for Reform," ibid, Nov.
20, 1958, p. 14.
|