America's Land Boom
Daniel M. Friedenberg
[Reprinted from Harper's Magazine, May, 1968]
Land is a prime buy. Year after year surveys of growth items
spotlight the rise in value of a small group of steady winners: old
paintings and graphic art, rare books and manuscripts, and antique
furnishings. Only after these comes the stock market: rarely does the
Dow-Jones average of thirty industrial issues come near the upward
thrust of art objects. Invariably, however, such surveys end by
pointing out that land prices equal or top the rise in all other
speculative investments. In a special issue devoted to land several
years ago, for instance, House and Home stated flatly that "since
World War II land speculation has created more millionaires than any
other form of business investment." The simplest and most obvious
reason for this is that the quantity of land is fixed while the
population grows and grows. The population of the United States in
1920 was 106 million; in 1960, 180 million; at present it is 200
million. According to the projections, by 1980, it will be 246 to 260
million, and by the year 2000, some 300 to 380 million. Thus within
the twentieth century the number of people occupying the same number
of square miles will have trebled. Actually, the amount of land being
inhabited by this growing population is shrinking, because urban
growth swallows a million acres a year, and highways and airports
absorb still more. In addition, both the government and private
corporations have been engaged in stockpiling, which, while it does
not diminish the actual amount of land, removes it from the domain of
speculation.
The sheer growth in affluence by itself has put great pressure on
land use, for it has led to such things as early marriage, larger
families, early retirement - all of which involve the spreading of
people into space.
Perhaps even more significant is the social revolution through which
America has been passing: that is, the accelerating flow of people
from rural to urban centers.
Another feature of this revolution has been the large-scale shift in
the work force from blue-collar workers to white. The U. S. Department
of Labor calculates that during the 1960s with a population increase
of 15 per cent, there will be a 30 per cent increase in the national
clerical force and a 40 per cent increase in professional and
technical personnel. Already one out of seven employees is a clerical
worker. One crucial result of the revolutionary new emphasis on
consumer goods and services has been the construction of larger and
larger office buildings, often packed together for convenience of
business. Another is the parallel construction of high-rising
residences nearby for the management elite - both bringing land values
up at a dizzying rate.
Despite these recent spurs to the growth in value of land, however,
that growth in itself is nothing new. Indeed, in an important economic
sense, the history of America can be said to be the history of the
rise in land values.
An exemplary case of the land boom is, of course, Florida. Before the
turn of the century, Henry M. Flagler, who was an original Rockefeller
partner, made many additional millions speculating in Florida land.
The islands comprising Miami Beach, however, did not even begin to
assume their present condition until after World War I. In 1920, the
assessed valuation of all real property on Miami Beach was only
$225,000. By 1925 permits for construction had been issued amounting
to over $17 million. Today there are individual estates on the small
islands in Biscayne Bay - such as those of Norman Woolworth of the 5 &
10s and William McKnight of Scotch Tape - valued at a million dollars
apiece.
Since World War II Florida real-estate speculation has drawn, as
flies to a honey pot, the richest men in America. Arthur Vining Davis,
after retiring as board chairman of Alcoa, concentrated on South
Florida real estate. When he died at the age of ninety-five in 1962,
he owned one-eighth of Dade County, shopping centers, and ocean-front
property in Miami and Sarasota. He was considered the fifth-richest
man in the U. S., with a fortune estimated at some $350 million. Davis
was only one of many: John MacArthur, the Murchison brothers, John Hay
Whitney, Gardner Cowles, the Mackle brothers, and William and Alfred
Vanderbilt all hold or have held enormous land interests in the state.
Some of the profits realized by these men make the land trading of
John Jacob Astor in early Manhattan or the activities of Marshall
Field in late 19th-century Chicago look petty by comparison.
Florida is only one of the more spectacular instances of a trend
operating throughout the nation. Since 1945 average land prices have
more than tripled. Even farmland has been booming: during the past ten
years, according to the Department of Agriculture, its average value
has risen 70 per cent. The greatest jump has been in states enjoying a
benign climate; next have been suburban areas close to large cities;
and third in rise have been the downtown areas of certain cities.
In terms of physical size, the leader is California, which once
created the realty fortunes of Huntington, Stanford, Hopkins, and
Crocker, and is still an El Dorado for speculators. Some one thousand
persons a day stream into the state, and daily births in the young
population add seven hundred more. Manufacturing jobs since 1950 have
increased 80 per cent or eight times the national rate. Land prices in
San Francisco are second only to New York City. Southern California,
with its ideal climate, has seen the price for suburban land rising at
an annual rate of about $800 an acre.
J. Paul Getty and the Tishman interests are strong in California,
particularly in and around Los Angeles. There is also a new young
generation of speculators. Arthur Carlsberg, not yet thirty-five, hit
upon a technique to "harvest the farms" of Southern
California, and at last report had made over $5 million by buying
outlying farmland for subdivision. Joan Irvine, no older than
Carlsberg, is an even more impressive case. She is principal heiress
to over one-fifth of the Irvine Company, a ranch welded out of three
Spanish land grants. The Irvine Ranch, some 138 square miles, and
reaching from the Pacific Ocean to the Santa Ana Mountains south of
Los Angeles, may be the world's most valuable remaining feudal fief.
Dreary waste short years ago, the Irvine land, if sold intact, would
probably fetch half a billion dollars - and twice that if liquidated
piecemeal.
What is true for California is true for the Southwest in general. In
1962 a New Mexican real-estate broker put out a brochure asserting
that over the previous twenty years Albuquerque land had increased
annually in value an average of 25 per cent. Phoenix -where an
estimated 30 per cent of the land within city limits is held by
speculators - experienced a jump in population from 107,000 in 1950 to
439,000 in 1960; the city expects to hit the million mark by 1980. The
population growth of Tucson is even more fantastic. Its population was
46,000 in 1946, 250,000 in 1961, and is slated to approach two million
in the late 1970s.
Innumerable land millionaires have been the result. Perhaps the one
who has received the most publicity is David H. Murdock, operating
from Phoenix, whose interests extend through the Southwest and into
California. Then there is Thomas E. Hull, a Californian who thought of
building a hotel in the desert on the run between Salt Lake City and
California, near a small town in Nevada by the name of Las Vegas,
population 8,000 in 1941. He bought 57 acres at $100 an acre. This
land was valued in 1961 at over $5 million. Recently the eccentric
multimillionaire Howard Hughes has put down more than $40 million in
cash to acquire four Las Vegas casino hotels and seems intent on
buying out the rest of the city (not so coincidentally, Nevada has no
state income or inheritance taxes).
An adjunct of the Southwest and California, psychologically speaking,
is Hawaii. Here it is the Rockefellers* and the Kaisers who have taken
hold. Like the Irvine Ranch, Hawaii more closely resembles a feudal
barony than a state of the Union. Almost half of it is owned by sixty
large landowners, closely knit families who preempted the best land
when America took over the island group. These landowners have
consistently leased rather than sold; a measure of their current worth
is the fact that land around Honolulu which sold for $1,200 an acre
before statehood shot up to $20,000 an acre within the decade.
Back East, too, population growth is having much the same effect. In
The Great Gatsby, published in 1925, F. Scott Fitzgerald describes
Long Island's Nassau County: "About halfway between West Egg and
New York the motor road hastily joins the railroad and runs beside it
for a quarter of a mile, so as to shrink away from a certain desolate
area of land. This is a valley of ashes ..." In the ten years
from 1953 to 1963, the population of this county leaped from 700,000
to 1,500,000-and the pocketbooks of men like the Levitts, Alfred L.
Kaskel, and Samuel J. Lefrak swelled accordingly.
What Creates Land Values
It is essential to bear in mind that land itself is useless; what
creates its value is what is done to it. Frequently land is "improved"
by factors quite extraneous to it, such as the construction of nearby
roads, bridges, railroad sidings, or jet airports. Staten Island was
only fifteen years ago a bucolic retreat boasting no more than 3 per
cent of New York's inhabitants. Now the Verrazano-Narrows Bridge which
connects the island with Brooklyn, completed in 1964, has helped to
double its population in less than five years. Land values have jumped
a minimum of 400 per cent over the past decade, and certain large
blocks of farmland have jumped even more: farms selling for $3,000 to
$6,000 an acre in 1959 went up to $20,000 to $30,-000 an acre. Even
the municipal government, which once owned the greater part of Staten
Island, got on the bandwagon and began to sell off its holdings as
fast as they could be mapped.
The same thing happens each time a major artery is added to an urban
center. The taxpayers of New York State spent more than $400 million
to build the New York Thruway, and the immediate effect was to add
much more than that amount to the land prices along the route. The
Tappan Zee Bridge - connecting the White Plains area with Nyack on the
other side of the Hudson River - was first opened to traffic in 1955.
It had been predicted that after twenty years the bridge would be used
by some twelve million vehicles per year, but as it happened, within
the first decade fifteen million vehicles were crossing annually;
Rockland County, on the far side of this bridge, is now the
fastest-growing area in all New York State. Yet another example is
that of the Long Island Expressway, which made accessible an area in
Babylon Township where land prices then tripled in four years.
The federal government has long played a major role in this sort of
land improvement. The great boom in Western land after the Civil War
was a direct consequence of Washington's having subsidized the
transcontinental railroad. Today, the government's space program is
having much the same effect on the thousand-mile crescent which
stretches from Florida's Atlantic coast to the Texas panhandle. The
space industry, of course, is focused on three points, Cape Kennedy,
New Orleans, and Houston, but the benefits are seeping out on all
sides. Washington expects to spend $2 billion a year - more than the
entire $1.2-billion cost of the Tennessee Valley Authority - for
twenty years on space projects. What these plans have already done to
realty values will seem obvious. At Cape Kennedy, for example, the
same tract was sold three times in three years: first at $500 per
acre, next at $1,250 per acre; and then at $1,850 per acre. The
property is worth much more today.
The major U. S. corporations are also deeply involved in the land
boom. In some instances they are stockpiling against future demand in
a dwindling market, in some they are purely speculators, and often
they are serving as developers. Real estate has always been a side
occupation of the life-insurance companies, one that follows naturally
from the nature of their mortgage investment holdings. Many other
companies, however, only vaguely related, or related not at all, to
mortgage holding and land ownership, have come to occupy themselves
with it. The railroads still own enormous tracts from their original
land grants, and the Pennsylvania Railroad and the New York Central
Railroad (recently merged) have both been developing their own land
and cosponsoring enormous projects in various cities, especially
Dallas and Atlanta. The Pennsylvania is a partner in the new
$116-million Madison Square Garden Center in New York City, the Penn
Center commercial development in Philadelphia, and owns a majority
interest in separate operating realty corporations amounting to over
$200 million. Southern Pacific and Union Pacific are also active.
The oil companies, with fat depletion allowances to invest, are
becoming major land developers. Standard of California is investing
many millions in 1,500 acres near Los Angeles. Humble Oil is
developing 22,000 acres near Houston, already having invested $30
million. Gulf Oil has taken over the tremendous new residential
community of Reston, Virginia. Sunset International Petroleum is so
deep in real estate, mainly in California, that its oil business might
be called secondary.
The rush into land development in fact seems to be nearly universal:
Union Carbide has set aside a multimillion-dollar fund to acquire
acreage in what the company defines as "strategic areas."
Bethlehem Steel invested $13 million in 1964 in land near San
Francisco and an undisclosed sum more recently to buy thousands of
acres in Maryland. General Motors has actually established its own
real-estate division, Argonaut Realty; the company is also a partner
in its new headquarters building, now rising at Fifth Avenue and 59th
Street in New York City. Sears, Roebuck is a heavy land investor.
Alcoa, perhaps the most deeply involved, took over the major
Zeckendorf properties in Philadelphia and New York City, and has been
called one of the largest landlords in America. Alcoa has a
$500-million project in Los Angeles, a "city within a city"
of some 180 acres. Alcoa's rival, Reynolds Metals, already has over
$300 million invested in various projects in Philadelphia, Syracuse,
Providence, and Hartford. Westinghouse acquired one of the largest
land developers in Florida. And, as if to settle the matter once and
for all, Wall Street is now entering the field, principally the
banking house of Lazard Freres and the august firm of Eastman Dillon.
All of these factors have come together in a unique and yet broadly
revealing way on the island of Manhattan. Unlike many other places,
Manhattan has been a land investor's haven for 150 years. Being the
principal port for shipping from Europe, the reception center for wave
after wave of new immigrations, nerve center for the corporate life of
the entire nation, and headquarters for the United Nations,
Manhattan's relatively meager land supply has proven to be a
never-ending source of wealth. The early speculations of the
Rhinelanders, Beekmans, Phippses, Stuyvesants, Goelets, Roosevelts,
and especially the Astors still keep their descendants rich. The
grandchildren of the speculators of the early twentieth century - the
duPonts and the Rockefellers - have enlarged their inheritance.
Post-World-War-I land plungers such as the late William Randolph
Hearst and Joseph P. Kennedy retain gilded properties, though the
Kennedy family has sold much of its Manhattan real estate and
concentrated on Chicago. And the children of the crop of the 1920s,
the Tishmans, Rudins, Roses, Bursts, Minskoffs, and Urises, have now
been joined by the post-World-War-II group, John Galbreath, Peter B.
Ruffin, and the Fisher and Tisch brothers.
Although the city has lost actual population in the flight of the
middle class to the suburbs, office space has increased by some 40 per
cent during the last decade. Indeed, it is claimed that there has been
more new office space built in Manhattan since the end of World War II
than exists in any other city of the world. This one small island
houses headquarters for thirty-eight of the top one hundred industrial
corporations in America. In the five years from 1957 to 1962 the
number of clerical workers in Manhattan grew by around 200,000 (thus,
if you add their families, the mere increase in clerical workers is
equivalent to the population of a medium-sized city). Nor do even
these statistics keep pace with the tremendous daily expansion in this
area.
But the boom in offices is only one side of the story. The almost
equally rapid shift in the city's social and ethnic composition is the
other; and the two together have created an explosive speculative
compound - one that can give off large-scale failure as well as
success. (The misfortunes of Louis J. Glickman, the former top realty
syndi-cator, and of the by-now fabled William Zeckendorf will
illustrate.) It is not generally realized, but the larger part of
Manhattan's land is priced today below its value forty years ago. Much
of the upper part of the island, all of Harlem, the West Side above
72nd Street, the East Side below 8th Street and above 96th Street, is
decaying and/or subject to some form of subsidized urban-renewal
projects.
Manhattan's Favored Enclaves
When people talk of the amazing rise in Manhattan land values, they
are really referring only to four areas. The first is the mixed
residential and business strip from 34th Street north to 86th Street,
and at some points to 96th Street, extending east from Sixth Avenue to
the East River. The second is the financial district east of Broadway
and south of Fulton Street, now being extended west by the World Trade
Center and north by the Brooklyn Bridge Southeast project. The third
is the residential sections in Greenwich Village and around Lincoln
Square, site of the new Center for the Performing Arts. And the
fourth, only now coming into its own, is the area between Sixth and
Eighth Avenues, from 32nd to 59th Streets. Fingers of heightened land
value, of course, string out from these nuclei, but in the main they
are White ghettos of apartment houses and office buildings surrounded
by a setting of urban decay.
Within these favored enclaves, land values are breathtaking and seem
to keep on going up. Well-located Lincoln Center land was valued at
$20 to $30 a square foot when the cultural center was announced a
decade ago. Though the entire project is not yet complete, the best
unimproved Broadway sites today command a price close to $100 a foot.
Land in that peculiar narrow belt that comprises the financial
district has without question risen in value at least 50 per cent in
the last ten years. As for Greenwich Village, many years ago a certain
Captain Randall left $7,000 and 21 acres of land extending irregularly
from 8th to 10th Streets east of Fifth Avenue to help establish a a
retired sailors' home in New York City: leased out by Sailors' Snug
Harbor for apartment construction, these acres have a present value of
close to $100 million.
Manhattan's real gold mine, however, is in the Grand Central area.
Commodore Vanderbilt by a clever bit of legerdemain acquired for his
New York Central Railroad the land running on both sides of Park
Avenue from 42nd to 50th Street. In 1942 this land was valued at $70 a
square foot; today it leases on an equivalent basis for $500 a square
foot, the highest valued land in the world. There is some evidence
that all those battles waged for control of the New York Central have
more to do with this real estate than with the profits from its
railroad system.
Throughout the rest of this area extending north of 42nd Street and
east of Sixth Avenue, fortunes have been made since World War II. The
Astor estate - which for purposes of the death tax largely liquidated
most of its holdings-still holds certain parcels, particularly on
Sixth Avenue. And all the most aggressive builders have bought or
leased land here: the Bursts on Third Avenue, the Urises on Park
Avenue and Sixth Avenue, Tishman Realty on Park Avenue and Third
Avenue, and the Minskoffs on Lexington Avenue.
As a result of demand, almost all the major land sites have been
acquired for office buildings on these main streets, and this in turn
has driven up the value of the remaining land. There now seem to be
symptoms of a real-estate frenzy similar to that which seized Florida
in the mid-1920s. Park Avenue, Madison Avenue, and Fifth Avenue have
almost no sites available between 42nd and 57th Streets. First Avenue
and Seventh Avenue, and to a lesser extent Second Avenue, are still
considered fringes, though a westward movement began with the
Minskoffs acquiring the old Hotel Astor on Broadway and 44th Street
for a fifty-story skyscraper and the Urises' plans to build a
fifty-one-story tower on the site of the Capitol Theater at Broadway
and 50th Street. The result is that every storekeeper who years ago
bought his small building to protect his store lease on the ground
floor (usually with $5,000 cash and a string of mortgages), as well as
every speculator who holds "a piece" of a decayed brownstone
off these key streets, is convinced that just six months more, just
holding out another year, and he will come to fortune.
Speculators vs. Homeowners
Frenzied or not, land speculation is an integral part of American
economic activity. The courageous speculator is a dynamic force in our
nation. Without risk capital devoted to future expansion, without
daring and optimistic projection, the American people would never have
conquered a continent and created a standard of living the envy of the
world. But certain problems are created by this land speculation which
must be dealt with in the immediate future or the very daring which
created our dynamism may, in a new climate and a new age, do the
reverse and paralyze national growth.
To understand why this is so, we must understand the difference
between land and other commodities. Unimproved land is distinct from
other private property. It has not been created by any of its owners.
Moreover, as we pointed out earlier, its value is often enhanced by
what others who do not own it do to it. As John Stuart Mill once
remarked, "Landlords grow rich in their sleep." What he
meant, of course, was precisely what we have seen: that the increase
in population automatically makes land more valuable. Thus the
distinction between a successful and an unsuccessful land speculator
often has more to do with the ability to interpret and predict the
movement of population than with sagacity about how to improve the
land itself.
A further difference between unimproved land and all other
commodities in our society is that it is subject to lower taxes than
they. This fact has its roots in history. Present tax policy was
established at a time when most Americans were farmers and when the
society's foremost problem was to get the nation settled. The age-old
distrust of the city dweller by the freehold farmer - in America
intensified by the fact that the farmer tended to be white and
Anglo-Saxon old American, while city immigrants were of different
ethnic and religious backgrounds - blossomed into the kind of tax
policy that could automatically be supported by rural-dominated
legislatures. Nationally the result has been that, according to the
last statistics, raw land is assessed at less than 20 per cent of its
true market value while single-family homes are assessed at 32 per
cent. The speculator thus need pay only 62 cents in real-estate taxes
as compared to the dollar paid by the homeowner next door. When
farmers made up the vast majority of the population, this made sense.
Today, however, they are only a small minority (even among these, many
are fully mechanized, big-business farmers at that). The sense - at
least for the society as a whole - has departed.
Homeowners have also continued to support this policy - although for
a different motive than the farmers. For even though the homeowner is
at a distinct disadvantage vis-a-vis the land speculator, he is still
better off in this regard than the owners of multiple dwellings and
commercial structures. He is therefore afraid that any change in
taxation will hurt him. Within any given community homeowners comprise
a significant political bloc; their fears can be played on to muster
support for tax policies whose main thrust is to serve the interests
of speculators.
In 1964 Eugene Nickerson, Nassau County Executive, started a campaign
to raise assessed valuations on vacant land. Mr. Nickerson pointed out
that land speculators were taxed much lower than homeowners. He also
showed that the value of vacant land had shot up far higher than
improved land since the obsolete tax system had been put into effect
many years before; to little avail -- the furor raised by whipped-up
homeowners made the headlines in all the New York newspapers. Such
misguided agitation on the part of home-owners very often results in
the exact opposite of what they intend. Land speculators deliberately
keep land idle because of the low taxes. The home-owner, along with
apartment and commercial property owners, pays higher taxes on his
improved land, in effect subsidizing the land speculators who simply
wait for the entire community to push up the price of their land.
In fact, the political marriage of convenience between big land
speculators and homeowners has, if anything, helped to reduce the
proportionate weight of taxes on land. Fifty years ago land carried
nearly one-half the total tax load. Today, while it constitutes
one-third of our total national wealth, land carries less than 5 per
cent of the total tax load. Preferential tax treatment makes land that
is vacant a top investment for speculators; why shouldn't they keep
this precious, dwindling commodity off the market as long as the
annual increase in market value exceeds the property taxes?
Particularly since, when they finally do sell the land, they are only
subject to a capital gains, or 25 per cent, tax on the profits.
It should be obvious, then, that land speculation tends to price
single homes out of the market-indeed, it would seem to be the largest
single factor in the meteoric rise in prices of single-family
dwellings. According to the latest available statistics, the
proportion of land cost to total product cost rose from 10 per cent in
1950 to 23 per cent in 1962. Land values in the suburbs have tripled
during the past decade - and would appear to be repeating this
performance yet again - while the homeowner's average real income is
estimated to have risen by no more than 30 to 40 per cent. A study
conducted in 1963 indicated that the same three-bedroom house would
cost about $35,000 within fifteen miles of Times Square and $14,000
fifty miles away.
The preferential treatment of speculators is also the major cause of
what has been called "urban sprawl." Because land is held
out of use until rising population forces the price up, developers are
forced to leapfrog over large vacant tracts, creating those jumbled
suburbs which are so typical of our major cities. The social costs of
servicing these communities, such as bringing gas and water and
electric lines to them, or creating autonomous police and fire forces,
are greatly raised as well.
Within the central city, the undertaxing of land has also directly
served to enhance the enrichment of slum owners. Since tax increases
are mainly levied against improvements rather than land, slumlords can
find it more profitable to do nothing. It pays them to let their
property deteriorate and take advantage of lower assessments.
Moreover, in addition to the cost in discomfort and demoralization to
those who must live in them, slum buildings also cost the community a
great deal more in the way of services such as fire and police
protection. Thus the property least taxed costs the general taxpayer
most. Slum clearance, then, is in fact cheap in the long run, paying
for itself by increasing taxable sources and reducing the social cost.
Current tax policy, on the other hand, tends to work just the
opposite.
Municipal authorities, who are perpetually in need of money, compound
the difficulty by loading more and more taxes onto improvements. And
the buildings which are a credit to the city are taxed far out of
proportion to its disreputable slums. This policy sometimes reaches
insanity, as in the famous case of New York's Seagram Building, whose
builders were taxed at an outrageous rate precisely because they had
put up such a brilliant piece of architecture. Therefore it not only
pays off immediately to cut corners in the design and construction of
new buildings, it continues to pay off in favorable carrying charges.
Making it advantageous to put up inferior structures is not exactly
sound social policy for American cities.
Who Profits from the Subway?
How then can contemporary society sensibly resolve the problem of
land values? The answer to this question is twofold. First, by
increasing the assessment on land in proportion as its value is
increased by extraneous factors, such as improvements in
transportation. And second, to tax it in relation to its actual value
rather than to its unimproved market value - that is, on the basis of
its use when it is improved rather than standing idle. The effort to
assess land in relation to local municipal improvements is an old
question in America. Almost half a century ago the City Club of New
York made a study of the cost of the Inter-borough subway system,
completed in 1908. The study showed that the subway had cost $43
million while the rise in property values amounted to over $80 million
for only the stretch from 135th Street north; in other words, property
owners in the northern section of the city received a gift almost
double in value to the entire cost of the subway. The City Club argued
that these property owners should pay an extra assessment rather than
have the entire city population taxed for their private benefit. Not
surprisingly, the proposal was successfully vetoed by pressure from
the interest parties. A recent study in Montreal came to the
conclusion that if local landowners were required to pay the city 5
per cent interest on its investment in the improvements which
increased the value their land, Montreal would be able to run
government without collecting any taxes at all.
In the matter of such improvements as the Verrazano-Narrows Bridge,
the Tappan 2 Bridge, the Long Island Expressway, and the New York
Thruway, the entire taxpaying public subsidized the cost, with local
individuals and speculators reaping great profits. If the system were
changed so that those who particularly benefit from the improvement
were to bear some part the cost, the beneficiaries would still come
out ahead with profits and the tax burden would reduced for the rest
of the community.
As to the problem of assessing land on the basis of use, there have
been several intelligent attempts to deal with it, mostly in the more
advanced Anglo-Saxon countries. Australia has gone furthest. In
Sydney, for example, land is taxed as though fully improved in
accordance with the district zoning. This drives out both land
speculators and slum owners, neither of whom can afford to pay the
full-use tax. A variation of this formula is used in Brisbane, which
forbids taxes on improvements but has a uniform 9 per cent tax on land
regardless of what is constructed on it. In addition to Australia,
many provinces in New Zealand and Western Canada subscribe in one
degree or another to the basic idea of "site-value taxation,"
which increases the tax on the unimproved land and diminishes or
exempts from taxation the improvement.
The approach taken in Denmark, somewhat less radical, is obviously
better suited politically to America. In Denmark both land and
improvements are taxed, but land at a steeper rate. In fact, one
American city, Pittsburgh, has already adopted a similar formula.
Pittsburgh taxes land at value while improvements are taxed at half
value. The tremendous building activity in that city, undertaken by
the Mellon interests with the backing of the largest life-insurance
companies, would seem to indicate that this policy encourages rather
than inhibits growth. As it was intended to do, it forces the
improvement of land.
Henry George, a most original nineteenth-century American economist,
went so far as to propose the abolition of all taxes but land taxes.
His "single tax" was intended to force land into its highest
and best use, offsetting the worst effects of land speculation and
obviating high profit from slums. Such an oversimplification of a very
complex tax problem as George's, of course, cannot stand up as the
cure-all he claimed. In an economy where leasehold arrangements,
long-term tenant commitments on fixed rentals, and heavy mortgages are
quite common, the introduction of a "single tax" would be
discriminatory and even confiscatory to an important class of
capitalistic investors.
Nevertheless, the fact that both
Life (December 24, 1965), and Fortune (October 1963),
highly esteemed conservative magazines, endorsed a modified approach
to the "single tax" theory, would seem to be evidence enough
that the call to adjust an inequitable tax policy is hardly flaming
radicalism. Indeed, from an historical view it can be said that it was
the narrow feudal policy of East European capitalists - holding land
and refusing to permit its development - that helped to create an
environment hospitable to the Communist take-over. This is even more
true in Latin America today.
Any study of land value must ultimately deal with the question of
what is our economic future. In a slump, everybody loses - the
speculator as well as the careful investor, the corporation that
behaves rapaciously as well as that which behaves prudently, and of
course the municipal authority, which suffers a decline in tax
revenue.
Nor is the question of the future one that can be answered with total
confidence, for capitalism has not yet invented techniques to ward off
depressions. We know that wise policies do serve to level off the
usual cycles of boom and bust: for instance, those devices that go by
the name of Keynesian economics which enable the government - through
interest control, public works, and tax inhibition or relaxation - to
influence the course of events. Unfortunately there is almost no such
policy of control with respect to land prices. One purpose of this
article is to suggest; that creating an equitable land-tax program
will encourage more stable growth.
As a matter of fact there is a new stabilizing factor today in land
speculation - albeit one whose contribution to the life of the greater
community is highly questionable. Much idle land of consequence is in
very strong hands, mainly certain rich families and corporations that
hold on despite temporary fluctuations. The bite of the capital-gains
tax discourages them from selling on a limited rise, and the power of
their purse enables them to resist dumping when the market declines.
They feel, with some reason, that rising population and the low taxes
they pay (which are fully deductible as expense items) must eventually
create a more favorable situation no matter how much they may
initially have overpaid for the land. Though this may be pernicious in
the social sense, it does at least to some extent help to inhibit the
wild swings in price that formerly characterized American land
speculation.
That these families and corporations can remain in their advantaged
position forever is open to doubt. Even assuming that there will be no
change in current land-taxation policy, the history of American
capitalism offers little reason to believe that there will be an "eternal
ascending plateau" of values. This theory is attractive, but
historically it is, I am afraid, bunk, as can be shown by the
following table.
Historic Land Price Swings
Year |
Population Increase |
Time Inverval |
Land Bust |
Time Interval |
1810-1820 |
33% |
10 years |
1819 |
- |
1830-1840 |
33% |
10 years |
1837 |
18 years |
1850-1860 |
36% |
10 years |
1857 |
20 years |
1870-1890 |
30% |
10 years |
1873 |
16 years |
1890-1900 |
21% |
10 years |
1893 |
20 years |
1920-1930 |
16% |
20 years |
1929 |
36 years |
1950-1960 |
20% |
20 years |
no bust |
38 years |
If the last 150 years of land values were graphed in relation to
subsequent readjustments, it would seem to indicate that intervals of
land bust are merely wider apart in the twentieth century and -
judging from 1929 - come with more violence as a result.
Of course, land values in the larger sense reflect the general
movement of the economy both in prosperity and depression. The fact is
that land seems to be a sensitive barometer, anticipating both future
declines and future rises. For example, 1929 was preceded by a sharp
farmland decline in 1920, a Florida land bust in 1925, and a retreat
in 1927 from the highest land prices. Similarly today, the weakness of
land prices in both the Southwest and Florida, and continued
sluggishness in California, may anticipate a more serious contraction.
But given a vigorous government which does not hesitate to enter the
domestic picture with programs of aid, research, and direct capital
expenditure, given the aggressive international policy of the Johnson
Administration, it would be foolhardy to prophesy. Anything can, and
does, happen in land prices.
*It has very recently been reported that
Laurance Rockefeller (Rock Resort) has sold to Eastern Airlines an
enormous package, consisting of the Dorado Beach development in
Puerto Rico, Cancel Bay Plantation in St. Johns (the U.S. Virgin
Islands), and his Hawaiian hotel project completed a few short years
ago. Daniel M. Friedenberg's article in "Harper's" in 1961
on "The Coming Bust in the Real-estate Boom" had a rocking
effect on the New York real-estate business, in which the
Friedenberg family has been active for 49 years. Mr. Friedenberg
received a B.S. degree at the Wharton School of Finance and
Commerce, and served in the Army in World War II. He writes for many
magazines, literary as well as professional, and is president of
several real-estate corporations.
|