Greece: Her Economic Background
Pavlos Giannelia
[Reprinted from Land and Freedom, March-April
1941]
ONCE again in her long history, Greece is indicating to her wavering
neighbors that there is another answer than unconditional submission
to be given to the all-levelling march of empire and to the threat of
devastating weapons.
While the immediate outcome is still uncertain, the world has been
inspired to witness a new Thermopylae, another Marathon, a second
Salamina.
But these are military and political matters. Though they are more
spectacular, behind them lies the economic question. What is the
economic background of Greece? To understand this question, it is
necessary to delve into the Greek tradition leading up to the present.
After many centuries of tithe-collecting governments, after
Hammurbian, Egyptian and Mosaic legislations in the near East, after
Aegean and Homeric rulings in Greece, there arose Lycurgus, the man
whom the Delphic Oracle pronounced as "god rather than man."
Lycurgus gave his laws to Sparta, the forerunner of totalitarian
governments. The laws were a multitude of minute prescriptions,
concerning not only landed property and government, but also the
organization of the family, the education of the children, private
life itself.
Sparta was a military community, and the Spartans constituted a
permanent army. At his birth, the Spartan was examined by a council,
and only if found physically fit was he given to his mother. The
Spartan's birthright was 17 acres of the public land. At the age of
seven his formal education began. He was introduced into a group of
children who were led by a boy distinguished for his intelligence and
valor. Physical training occupied the chief place in his education.
Girls went through the same physical training as the boys. At twenty
the Spartan entered the army ; at thirty he became a citizen, but was
obliged to continue his military life.
In addition to the soldiers, the mass of Spartan population consisted
of perioekes (neighbors), who were nominally free men; helotes,
servile peasants, though not slaves; and pure slaves, who are rarely
mentioned by ancient authors. The perioekes, permitted to own land in
certain areas, practiced agriculture, trade, the arts and
manufacturing. Helotes were similar to the Medieval feudal tenants,
not permitted to leave the land they cultivated.
Quite a different set of laws from those of Lycurgus were those of
Solon, the archon of Athens, to whom his fellow citizens entrusted (in
594 B. C.) the formulation of laws which should reconcile the nobles
and the people. Besides his more transient measure (seisachthia) for
settling the disproportionate debts of the indigent population, Solon
promulgated the laws which formed the constitution of the Athenian
state, the "fatherly policy" of the golden age of Greek
democracy.
Plutarch relates as follows: "As Solon intended to leave the
government in the hands of the well-born, and at the same time also to
allow the common people to participate, he took as the basis the
fortune of the citizens. First class citizens were those who produced
five hundred bushels of produce; these were called pcntakosiamedimnes.
As second class citizens he chose those who were able to feed a horse,
or to produce three hundred bushels; they were called 'horsemen.' The
third class were called zeugites, and their measure was two hundred
bushels. The rest were all called thetes; they were not allowed to
rule, but could participate as hearers in the Assembly and the
Tribunal."
Thus the participation in the administration of the state, its duties
and the obligation to defend it, seemed fitting to Solon to rest
proportionately on the landed gentry. The pentakosiamedimnes could
aspire to the highest place in government the position of archon.
Their duties were to pay naval expenses, and to serve in the cavalry.
The second class citizens had to furnish military equipment and also
to serve in the cavalry. The third class citizens formed the infantry.
From the ranks of the second and third classes came the employees of
the state. All the others, the thetes, even the merchants and
manufacturers, were land-poor or landless, and had no participation in
public service, neither did they have any taxes to pay or military
services to fulfill.
It can be seen that the most important qualification for sharing the
duties and privileges of government was the ability to produce
dynamenos. Thus, the fertility of the land, not the extent of the
property nor the investments of labor and capital, was the measure of
advantages and obligations. This subtle distinction has been neglected
by most economists. That Solon made the distinction is interesting
from Georgeist point of view. It is also significant that Solon
abolished the term telos (taxes), and spoke of the obligations that
had to be paid to settle the budget as litourgies (people's works).
One is reminded that modern Danish legislators avoid the term "land
value taxation," and refer to the public collection of rent as
Grundskyld (ground debt).
Once again in the tenth century A.D. the then Greek Asia Minor
furnished a sample of the combination of military service and
landownership. The Byzantine emperors Leo III, Romanes, Phogas,
Tsmiskis and Basil II, settled in their conquered territory the
akrites, those valiant warriors who helped them recapture the Eastern
Roman Empire from Sicily to the Caucasus, from the Adriatic to the
Indian Ocean.
This commendable sort of feudalism was accompanied by a prohibition
on large landowners to buy out the holdings of the small peasantry.
Even more than that, the allilenyyon (mutual warranty) made the large
holders responsible for the arrears in taxes of their smaller
neighbors, so that they were interested in the highest degree in
helping these poorer fellows to make their way.
Over a thousand years later 1923 Greece delivered a blow to the
Malthusian theory of overpopulation. In that year Turkey exchanged her
Orthodox Greek population with the Mohammedan population of Greece.
The land distribution that Greece administered for this influx of
population the sort of distribution which Henry George discouraged is
perhaps the only case in which such a method succeeded, because it was
ethically motivated and was attended by economic as well as
nationalistic considerations.
In other countries, land distribution and movement of peoples has
failed, because there were usually little other than political
motives. To quote only one example: Czechoslovakia, which distributed
28% of its land to the Czech legionnaires, increased its population by
10% ; but the peasantry decreased by 1%. The bill was paid in
September, 1938 and March, 1939, when the frustrated Slovakian, Polish
and German populations took their revenge.
The Greco-Turk exchange of population increased the population of
Greece by 47%. This resulted in a 40% increase in the corn fields, a
67% increase in the vineyards, a doubling of oil and olive crops and
sheep breeding, a doubling of imports, and a tripling of tobacco crops
and general exports. Notwithstanding this brilliant effect of the
increase of population, the Malthusian theory is so deep-rooted in the
minds of the legislators that no attempt was made to attract the Greek
population of other neighboring countries, or to encourage "foreigners"
who desired to settle in Greece. The attitude of the legislators also
causes them to tax heavily the products of labor and to hamper trade
by "protective" duties and other restrictions. If only they
would return to the policy of Solon ! It is perhaps a small
consolation that Greece has been the first country to be officially
represented at a Henry George Congress the International Conference at
Copenhagen in 1926 and at Edinburgh in 1929.*
Let us hope that Metaxas' successor, Mr. Corizis, who began his
ministry by suppressing the bank-depot restrictions, will not fail to
restore to Greece a fuller economic freedom after the end of the
present ideological struggle. The modern form of the Solonian
tradition, which Greece so sorely needs, would be a single tax on land
values and free trade in its fullness.
******
* Mr. Giannelia was the official representative of the Greek
government at these two Conferences.
|