Albert Jay Nock --
Truly a Superfluous Man
Oscar B. Johannsen
[Reprinted from Fragments, April-June, 1982]
That unique poetic genius, T. S. Eliot, cared little for those
publicists who for the moment are in the public eye because they are
in tune with the public's particular foible or prejudice. Rather, he
was interested in the "few writers preoccupied in penetrating to
the core of the matter, without ambition to alter the immediate course
of affairs, and without being downcast or defeated when nothing
appears to ensue."
He may not have had Albert Jay Nock in mind when he penned the above,
but that he was describing a person like Nock is irrefutable. Whether
one reads The Theory of Education in the U.S.; Our Enemy,
the State; Henry George; or Memoirs of a Superflous
Man, the conclusion is the same. Nock indeed goes to the core of
the subject matter in question, and in such an effortlessly elegant
and lucid style as to be the envy of every aspiring writer.
For him, education is a maturing process to be obtained by the study
of literature, as that of Greece and Rome, for it "covers
twenty-five hundred consecutive years of the human mind's operations
in poetry, drama, law, agriculture, philosophy, architecture, natural
history, philology, rhetoric, astronomy, politics, medicine, theology,
geography, everything." Such a study does not necessarily make
one more adept at making a living, but rather helps one attain that
degree of maturity which distinguishes the cultured man or woman from
the all too prevalent mass man.
And the State, "both in its genesis and by its primary
intention, is purely anti-social. It is not based on the idea of
natural rights, but on the idea that the individual has no rights
except those that the State may provisionally grant him." Nock
wryly observed that "instead of recognizing the State as 'the
common enemy of all well-disposed, industrious and decent men,' the
run of mankind, with rare exceptions, regards it not only as a final
and indispensable entity, but also as, in the main, beneficent."
Despite his loathing of the State, or more probably because of his
contempt for it, he said he "once voted at a Presidential
election. There being no real issue at stake, and neither candidate
commanding any respect whatever, I cast my vote for Jefferson Davis,
of Mississippi. I knew Jeff was dead, but I voted on Artemus Ward's
principle that if we can't have a live man who amounts to anything, by
all means let's have a first-class corpse. I still think that vote was
effective as any of the millions that have been cast since then."
For Nock, economics was hardly the obscure and arcane mystery that
economists often try to portray it to be. He argued that "fundamental
economics are very simple," and implied that essentially all one
had to do was to use common sense. He remarked on the curious ideas
which have arisen with regard to money. He noted, "One such
belief is that commodities - goods and services - can be paid for with
money. This is not so. Money does not pay for anything, never has,
never will. It is an economic axiom as old as the hills that goods and
services can be paid for only with goods and services.
"
But people have lost sight of this simple fact that "everything
which is paid for must be paid for out of production, for there is no
other source of payment."
Though Nock at one time was in agreement with the general impression,
which still prevails, that mankind has a deep-seated love of liberty,
he sadly "discovered scarcely a corporal's guard of persons who
had any conception whatever of liberty as a principle, let
alone caring for any specific vindications of it as such."
You, the reader, should not read any of Nock's works unless you are
not of the common mold. You must be willing, as Nock says, to go "back
to the classics of a subject for the practical purpose of saving
yourself a lot of work. You get an accumulation of observation,
method, technique, that subsequent experience has confirmed, and you
can take it at second-hand and don't have to work it all out afresh
for yourself.
It is just good sense." Nock's experience had
been that few Americans had the patience to read the classics on any
subject, which is why so many fall prey to other people who have had
some knowledge of what previous generations did.
If you have not had the pleasure of reading any of Nock's works, if
you wish to get some idea of the flavor of Nock's ideas, you can do no
better than to read Cogitations from Albert Jay Nock, which
contains selections from Nock's works arranged by Robert M. Thornton,
published by The Nockian Society, Irvington-on-Hudson, New York 10533.
If you do not come away with the desire to read as much of Nock as
you can get your hands on, you are beyond hope. You would be far
better advised to continue to read the torrent of contemporary "liberal"
bilge which passes for profound intellectualism today. But if you do
delve avidly into Nock, not only will your perception of the world
about you be broadened, but you will have attained some bit of
timeless knowledge and tolerance which will enable you to enjoy life,
even though you are forced to watch helplessly as today's mass-man
works, in his own assiduous fashion, to make an intolerable mess of
things.
|