Federal Land Taxes in the United States
J. Edward Jones
[Reprinted -- with minor editing -- from Land and
Freedom, January-February, 1934]
Is the present Federal Constitution broad enough to permit Congress
to enact a Federal Single Tax? Have we ever had a Federal tax on land
values? Would the procedure for valuation and collection be so
involved as to discourage the plan?
Paragraph 3, Section 2, of Article I, U. S. Constitution contains the
following: "Representatives and direct taxes shall be apportioned
among the several States which may be included within this Union,
according to their respective numbers, which shall be determined by
adding to the whole number of free persons, including those bound to
service for a term of years, and excluding Indians not taxed,
three-fifths of all other persons." Paragraph 4, Section 9, of
the same article, provides: "No capitation, or other direct tax,
shall be laid, unless in proportion to the census or enumeration
herein before directed to be taken."
Reference to the Debates of the Constitutional Convention fails to
show why direct taxes were required thus to be apportioned. However,
in the fifty-fourth number of the Federalist, Alexander Hamilton
explains it. He shows that the rule for apportionment of members of
the House of Representatives among the States and for raising direct
taxes is the same. Commenting on the fact that the rule is not founded
on the same principle in each case, he says:
"In the former case, the rule is understood to
refer to the personal rights of the people, with which it has a
natural and universal connection. In the latter, it has reference to
the proportion of wealth, of which it is in no case a precise
measure, and in ordinary cases a very unfit one. But notwithstanding
the imperfection of the rule, as applied to the relative wealth and
contribution of the States, it is evidently the least exceptional
among those that are practicable, and had too recently obtained the
general sanction of America, not to have found a ready preference
with the Convention."
We may agree that population is an unfit measure of the proportion of
wealth and the contribution of the States. Yet we know that natural
opportunities for the production of wealth have not been showered
equally on all the States. Since men do tend to congregate and rear
families where opportunity exists, there may be more reason for this
as a basis for a tax on land monopoly than at first appears. Since all
economists of repute agree that that land ownership is a monopoly,
justice does not require that a tax on land values be laid as
accurately as one on wealth, which is a product of labor. Certainly
much less injustice is done Labor and Industry by using this as a test
than by using other present methods of taxation. A comparison of the
1930 census of the U.S. with the 1930 valuation of real property (land
values alone are not given) in the 1932 Statistical Abstract p. 205,
will show that the test is usable. If we want a better test, namely
that of land values, we can amend the article.
Historically, it is interesting to note that Congress has levied
taxes on land values in the United States, under the present
Constitution, on five different occasions. This occurred in 1798,
1813, 1815, 1816, and 1861. The fact that recouise was had to this tax
at the beginning of our financial history and in two war periods would
appear to show its value in times of emergency.
The legislation of 1798 may be considered typical. In addition, it
was adopted by men who actually wrote the present Constitution or were
contemporary leaders in its framing and adoption. These men were
familiar with the levenue schemes of the States of this peiiod and the
basis undeilying them. A study of the two laws passed in 1798, then,
should be a piactical, inductive source of the interpretation of these
Constitutional provisions. The first Art is entitled, "An Act to
provide for the valuation of Lands and Dwelling Houses, and the
enumeration of Slaves within the United States." 1 St. at Large
p. 580. The second is entitled, "An Act to lay and collect a
direct tax within the United States." 1 St. at Large p. 597.
Referring to the first Act, the "Act to provide for the
valuation and Dwelling Houses," etc., we find procedure for
valuation. Each State was divided into Divisions for purposes of
valuations, and a Commissioner was appointed for each Division. The
Commissioners of each State then met in a state-wide convention and
divided their respective Divisions into suitable and convenient number
of assessment districts, within each of which one respectable
freeholder was appointed principal assessor, and a sufficient number
of assistants to carry the Act into effect. The Commissioners, at this
meeting, were to prepare regulations and instructions for the
assessors.
The assessors, under the direction of the Commissioners, were to
inquire after value and enumerate dwelling houses, lands and slaves in
the following manner: Every dwelling house above the value of one
hundred dollars, with the outhouses and the lot on which such
buildings were located not exceeding two acres, was to be valued at
the rate such property was "worth in money with a due regard to
situation." All other lands and town lots, were to be "valued
by the quantity, either in acres, or square feet, as the case may be,
at the average rate which each separate and entire tract or lot is
worth in money, in a due relation to other lands and lots, and with
reference to all advantages, either of soil or situation," etc.
Other sections of the Act provide details as to form, penalties etc.
(Italics are mine throughout).
In the second Act, the "Act to lay and collect a direct tax,"
etc., it is provided that "a diiect tax of two millions of
dollars is laid upon the United States, and apportioned to the States
respectively, ...
By referring to the 1930 U. S. Census figures on the populations of
these States, we may compare the proportions these States would now
pay. For example, New York, with a population four times as large as
North Carolina would pay four times as much of the tax as North
Carolina, whereas in 1798 North Carolina paid more than New York.
The Act further provided that the tax should be assessed on dwelling
houses, lands and slaves, according to the valuations and enumerations
provided for in the first statute above referred to, and in the
following manner: Upon every dwelling house which, with the outhouses
appurtenant thereto, and the lot whereon the same are erected, not
exceeding two acres, shall be valued in a manner aforesaid, at more
than one hundred, and not more than five hundred dollars, there shall
be assessed in the manner herein provided, a sum equal to two-tenths
of one per centum on the amount of the valuation. If the value was
between $500 and $1,000, the tax rate was increased to three-tenths of
one per cent; if between $1,000 and $3,000, to four-tenths of one per
cent; if between $3,000 and $6,000, to five-tenths of one per cent. In
like manner the rate was likewise increased so that properties worth
$30,000 or more were taxed at the rate of one per cent of the value.
Each slave was arbitrarily taxed 50 cents.
The Act then provided, "And the whole amount of the sums so to
be assessed upon dwelling houses and slaves within each State
respectively, shall be deducted fiom the sum apportioned to each
State, and the remainder of the said sum shall be assessed upon the
lands within each State, according to the valuations to be made
pursuant to the act aforesaid, and at such rate per centum as will be
sufficient to produce the said reminder." Other sections provide
details.
Considering the above statutes, we find: First. Congress did not levy
the tax on land considered by area, but rather on land value. Second.
Congress chose to classify lands into two classes: lands with dwelling
houses, and lands, including town lots, not so improved. This
illustrates the power of Congress to classify lands and land values or
any other species of monopoly or property for taxing purposes. Should
Congress decide to exempt buildings and other improvements or homes
and farms under a certain value, it has the power to do so. Should it
decide to tax deposits of minerals or urban land, site value or land
value in general, it may. Third. Not only was the tax placed on land
values, but the rate was progressive. This out-Georges the Georgists.
This method, perhaps, is the answer to the much heralded doctrine of "ability
to pay." It permits a heavier rate on a vacant or inadequately
improved lot worth $10,000 than on one worth $100. Fourth. Most
singularly, Congress left the rate on lands and city lots without
dwelling houses to be set by a contingency; i.e. at a sufficient rate
to raise the remainder of the money needed. This proves that it is not
necessary that every detail in the procedure and results of taxing
land values need be known in advance. Application of this plan permits
a uniform rate to be levied on land values of sites adequately
improved or used, in all the States, with a provision that the
remainder of the quota of each State be raised by a tax rate
sufficient, when applied to vacant or inadequately used lands or other
natural resources, to raise the amount. The fact that the last named
rates are not uniform in all States is not a substantial objection,
because they are applied against monopoly and sloth and not against
industry. Fifth: The Act illustrates the old American custom of
penalizing home owners to help speculators in lands and city lots, by
making possible a lower rate on these last than the rates on lands
improved with dwellings. This is not the result of a taxation of land
values but rather on the method used in this particular Act.
Hence, the writer concludes that a Federal Single Tax is permissible;
if not the only tax, why should it not be used to take the place of
some of the numerous taxes on labor products?
It is submitted, however, that the requirement of apportionment
cannot be evaded by levying the tax on the privilege of owning or
using land, as probably could be done in England. English land titles
are based on the feudal system with the King as absolute owner, the
occupiers holding possession of various estates subject to the duty of
rendering rent or services in return to the King. The theory in the U.
S. is that the rights of the King at the time of the Revolution were
acquired by the people of the several States. Public lands west of the
Alleghanies were ceded by these States to the Federal government,
which in turn granted titles to settlers. The courts generally have
held, since we never had feudal tenure here, that the government
conferred absolute ownership or "allodial" titles, i.e.
titles free from rent or service and opposed to feudal holding.
Although this is the general view, it is subject to criticism at least
in the case of titles in the original thirteen States, in which the
titles theoretically, at least, were in the King of England until the
Revolution. Feudal tenure with its duties was not abolished in England
until 1660, and in those original States which accept the Common Law
existing up to 1607, considering the taking of title by the Cabots in
the name of the King, the rule would seem to be wrong.
Furthermore, the U. S. Supreme Court has held that the question of
whether a tax is a direct tax (requiring apportionment) is to be
determined not by the theories of economists alone but with regard to
historical consideration.
Granted that the ownership and use is in justice a privilege, yet
ownership of land has been considered by such monopolists as Lord Coke
and other builders of our legal concepts as a sacred right of
property. Federal judges, backed up by a public opinion which has not
considered these questions, would probably hold the tax on the
privilege a direct tax. When civilization has a keener sense of
justice and a better understanding of privilege, then it will not make
any difference about this problem. We will do away with such
restrictions and see to it that our governments have power to provide
revenues by legitimate means.
|