Production of Wealth
Leon Maclaren
[Chapter 2 from the book, Nature and Society,
, 1943]
The things which surround us have each very many functions. In trying
to understand their true nature, men following different lines of
study consider them in different aspects, and group them into classes
according to these aspects. Thus a botanist, going into a garden,
looks at the flowers, shrubs and trees and, for the purpose of his
science, classifies them into families and species. A chemist going
into the same garden would not see flowers, shrubs or trees at all,
but see combinations of the elements of oxygen, hydrogen, carbon and
the like. His classification would, consequently, be very different
from the botanist's. The economist would view the same garden in yet a
different way, for he would see land, labour, wealth and capital.
It is important that from the outset the things which together make
up the universe should be classified according to their several
economic functions. In defining each class, each "factor" in
the life of a community, care must be taken not to confuse together,
as though they belonged to one factor, things which operate
differently in social economy. Clearly, if this confusion is allowed,
further confusion will follow when an attempt is made to trace the
effect of each factor through the pattern of social relationships.
Conversely, unnecessary difficulties must ensue upon dividing into two
classes, as though they belonged to different factors, things which
are alike in their economic operation: to make distinctions where no
differences exist always leads to useless subtlety. In short, the
definition of each factor must be exhaustive, in that it includes
everything having the same economic function; and exclusive, in that
it does not include two things having different economic functions.
To each factor, as it is defined, a name will be given: and
thereafter the selected word will be used solely to mean the factor to
which it will have been attached, and will not be used in any other
sense.
NATURAL RESOURCES
The first great factor is the natural resources of the universe.
Abundantly different as are the forms which they take, all have the
same economic purpose and display the same peculiarities. Together
they constitute the storehouse from which man draws all he possesses.
Year in and year out, unless disturbed by man, they remain or
reproduce themselves in numbers and quantities so nearly the same,
that only after very long periods have elapsed can any substantial
change be noted. Man may discover new possibilities in these
resources, but he cannot add an ounce to their weight. Indeed it is
the secret of their creation which baffles science and is the subject
of disputes among religious teachers. To them, men must daily return
for both the necessities of life and its luxuries and refinements.
These natural resources are known in the language of economics as "land".
The word land, used in this sense, includes, not merely the minerals
which lie in the earth, but the wild beasts and birds which live upon
it and the oceans and waterways which flow in its hollows. It may be
defined as "all natural resources exterior to man himself".
The use of the word in this broad and sweeping sense is not peculiar
to economics. For example, in English law a man's land includes "all
that lies beneath the surface down to the very centre of the earth and
all that rests upon it even up to the heavens".
Thus, in England, if straight lines are drawn from the centre of the
earth passing through the boundaries of a man's estate and on up to
infinity, all that by nature lies between those lines is that man's
land. This was the reason why the Air Navigation Act, 1925, was
passed. Before its passage, according to this conception of a
landowner's rights, aeroplanes passing through the air over the
surface of a man's land, no matter how high, were trespassing.
This view of a landowner's powers, adopted by lawyers and economists,
is not the product of a fevered imagination, but is the appreciation
of hard facts. Man by his nature must operate from the surface of dry
land. If he penetrates below the surface, as in mining, he must
frequently return to it. If he flies into the air, he must land again.
If he sails across the oceans, he must return to port. It has been
said that the highest which a man has ascended into the air, added to
the deepest he has penetrated into the earth, are to the diameter of
the earth but as the skin of an apple to its diameter.
The man who controls a piece of the earth's surface effectively
controls all the natural resources to which access may be had from
that point. If one person owns all the land which in a particular part
of the world is suitable for airfields then he effectively controls
the air routes concerned. This is a common lesson of war. Should one
party gain the land suitable for airfields, then the aeroplanes of the
other are of little use. Again, control of the land suitable for ports
will give command of the oceans. Should a company have control of all
the land suitable for ports in a given area, then clearly that company
could quickly gain control of the exporting industries whose products
must pass through the ports. That is why Governments have found it
necessary to limit the powers of port owners and compel them to accept
all goods and ships upon payment of a fixed scale of dues. Where such
governmental control has not been exercised, then the exporting
industries have inevitably become dependent upon the port owners.
Again, there are many parts of the British coast where holiday-makers
who would enjoy the air and sunshine must pay a toll to the landowner
for the privilege, for he controls the salt air and warm sun. It is
for these reasons that the law recognises that the man who has the
control of the surface of the earth controls all that lies below it
and all that, by nature, rests above it, even to the sunshine which
plays upon it and the winds which blow over it. For the same reason,
economists, by very nearly universal consent, a most remarkable
condition, have called these natural resources "land".
As has been said, the natural resources are the first factor in our
economic life. In this book they will be called "land" and
the word will not be used in any other sense.
In this book "land" means all natural resources.
"A man's land" means all the natural resources
which the man controls by reason of his ownership of part of the
earth's surface, or by reason of the rights which he possesses over
land occupied by others.
THE HUMAN FACTORS
Without land there would be no human existence; but the earth and all
its riches will not maintain human beings unless they work. Man's life
and progress are dependent on the direction he gives to his activity,
and the energy, skill and knowledge he puts into it. This human
element in life may be considered from two aspects: the motivation
which starts and gives direction to it, and the work itself.
HUMAN DESIRES
It does not lie within the scope of this enquiry to probe into the
inner workings of the human being; to enquire how far his wish to live
in a particular manner, or to marry according to particular rites or
rear children in particular ways, springs from his native genius or
from the tradition of his race, the customs of his time or the
instruction of his teachers. Whatever the springs or sources of his
actions may be, they will flow together, intermingle and formulate
themselves in his conscious mind as his desires. Desires are the
beginning and their resolution the object of all human activity. No
sooner is one of them gratified than another comes in its place. Human
desires are the second great factor in social life. They may be in
turn, generous or mean, wise or foolish, but in each case they will
rule the conduct of a man or woman and, at times, will guide the
conduct of the greater part of a nation.
Fortunately it is not necessary to define what is meant by "human
desire", for though it would baffle definition everyone knows
what he means by it.
LABOUR
Most people desire to live, but man cannot live unless man works; his
life and progress are dependent upon his energy, skill and knowledge.
These last form the third great factor in economic life. They are the
human and individual contributions to life and in this book will be
called "labour". It is by this application of human energy
to the natural resources of the world under the direction of human
desire, by labour applied to land in order to gratify human desires,
that man lives. From these three factors have risen a hundred empires.
Without their interaction man would not be. For him they are the daily
support of life. Land must be constantly tilled and sown, quarried and
mined, and men must wish to do it. Were this continual work upon the
natural resources suspended for a short time, famine would afflict the
world.
For some reason which seems to have no scientific foundation
whatever, it has become popular to distinguish between different
occupations as though they were different in kind. Thus organization,
which is clearly part of human effort, has been classed apart from all
the rest, and the reward for organization has been dignified by the
special title of "wages of superintendence". It is a little
difficult to see why this should be done unless it is an attempt to
justify the undue reward which under modern conditions goes to those
holding high directorships or whose occupation is company promotion.
Apart from any other considerations, these occupations are not of such
an importance as would justify their being put on a higher plane than
the work of the scientist, the engineer and the scholar. In truth,
differences between occupations may call for different degrees of
ability, knowledge and skill, but clearly the difference is one of
degree and not of kind. All useful human exertion in our economic life
serves the same purpose, which is either to make the things or do the
things which will gratify human desire. Every occupation, however
menial, requires some knowledge, some skill and some power of
organization. All perform the same function and all are labour.
In this book the word "labour" means all human effort.
LAND, HUMAN DESIRES AND LABOUR
Land, human desires and labour are the three primary factors in
economic life. On them all else depends. This has always been and, so
far as we can tell, always will be. This rule applies in Russia as it
does in England; in China as it does in America. No differences in
human outlook, and no human devices can change this elementary truth.
Obvious as this is, yet, as will be demonstrated later, it is just
such elementary truths which are ignored in daily practice. The
inevitable sequel of this is that in every part of the social
structure difficulties arise which seem to have no relation to each
other upon a superficial view, but which really result from the denial
of truth.
Man is utterly dependent on land, human desires and labour, but of
the three land must come first. Obviously, labour could produce
nothing without land and under such conditions labour would quickly
cease to exist. On the other hand, land is in no way dependent on
labour. Some power greater than man must account for its existence.
To sum up, human life requires first the land, then desires to
gratify, and finally the application of labour to land. This is a
universal truth which knows no exception.
WEALTH
The multitude of things which man may win from the earth by the
cunning of his crafts is truly wonderful. By their agency he
constantly expands his powers to make and to do, so that there seems
no limit to what human ingenuity can perform. Even daily use and long
aquaintance seem unable to dull man's wonder and delight at his own
achievements. When man makes anything, however, the product of his
hands differs in many important respects from the land from which it
came. These differences are of fundamental importance and set very
definite limitations on man's activity. They may best be illustrated
by taking an example of man's products, such as a loaf of bread, and
contrasting it with the natural resources from which it came.
First it is apparent that without the land there would be no bread,
whereas without bread there certainly could be land.
Next, without labour there would be no bread, but labour is not
required for the existence of land, on the contrary labour is
dependent upon land.
Again, as soon as the loaf is complete, it begins to moulder and
decay. Land, on the other hand, if left undisturbed by man, goes on
for ever. The great primitive forests and the little woods, the giant
rivers and the little streams, the animal, bird and fish life continue
year in and year out as they have always done. True, there are in
progress great changes, but these are slow in their operation and
dominated by forces which as yet man cannot understand. However,
though the forms change, the life and energy locked in them go on. So
soon, however, as man interferes with the natural balance, forces come
into play which tend to restore it. Processes of decay put a limit to
the life of man's products as though Nature were reclaiming that which
she has allowed to be taken from her. In consequence of this, man must
constantly be repairing and replacing that which he makes. He may
devise means of protecting his manufactures from destruction, but
these very means must be maintained by constant effort. Thus with
refrigeration, the power must constantly be supplied to maintain the
required temperature and the refrigerators themselves must be kept in
repair and working order.
Lastly, there seems no limit to what man may produce from the land
provided he has access to it. If he lacks bread, he may make more
loaves. He cannot, however, increase the natural resources in the
smallest degree.
From all this it is clear that these things which man makes and which
are the means of his existence must be set aside in classifying the
factors of our life and put under another heading.
In this book the great family of human products will be called "wealth".
From what has gone before it is clear that these things, which are
called "wealth" in these pages, must not be confused with
the land from which they came, or with the energy, skill or knowledge
which gave them birth. Land is not wealth. On the contrary, it is the
source of all wealth - something which must come before wealth can
exist. It is one, and only one, of the factors in the production of
wealth.
Much confusion seems to arise because, it is said, a man who owns
land is wealthy. A moment's thought will show, however, that it is not
the land which makes him wealthy, but the things he obtains from it or
in exchange for the use of it. By such means he may acquire food,
clothing, houses, cars and the like. If, though he has the land, he
can obtain none of these things, he will die. It is not the land that
makes him wealthy but the things he acquires from it. If he has a
house it will shelter him; if he has food he may eat it; if he has
clothes he may wear them; but land of itself, unless he works or
someone else will work for him, will provide none of these things.
So it is with skill and knowledge. No one would say that a highly
skilled architect beggared in unemployment is a wealthy man. If he
cannot, or does not, turn his skill and his knowledge to the
acquisition of the means of life he is a poor man indeed. Skill and
knowledge are not wealth. They are not even "potential wealth".
They are human attributes. In use they are part of labour; idle, they
are of no avail.
Another notion which is barbarous and ill-founded, but which has
found much countenance in economic thought, is that slaves are wealth.
Are men to be confused with cabbages? Slaves are men, just as are
landowners and labourers, which is reason enough, one would think, to
distinguish them from the inanimate creations of man's hands. The sun
warms them as it does other men; frost chills them; hope buoys them up
and fear makes them despondent. They respect their parents, love their
children and revere God as do other men. Are these unfortunate
creatures of God to be classed together with the senseless machines
grinding their iron jaws in our factories?
Doubtless all these confusions have come from a definition of wealth
which is now generally taught, but which pays no regard to those
elemental differences which mark out from one another the great
classes of things which make up man's economic life. This definition
states that wealth is anything having value, which usually means in
such writings anything that can be sold on the market. Certainly land
has value, slaves have value, man's creations have value and much of
all this can be sold on the market. It would be surprising if it were
otherwise. Anything that man desires can usually be sold on the
market. Obviously, he desires the land without which he could not
live. Men there will be who desire to have slaves, for then they can
live without working. The reasons, however, which lead men to desire
these things are different and reflect the differences between their
economic functions. It it these differences which are of importance
and which must be kept in mind if a true understanding of economic
life is to be obtained.
Treasury notes, the King's coinage, bank bills, mortgages, bonds and
promissory notes all have market prices. They are commonly thought of
as wealth. If, however, all these documents and coins were reduced to
so much paper, ink or metal, the amount of wealth in the world as a
whole would clearly not be lessened. Conversely, if two men were to
sit up all night writing each other cheques and bills of exchange,
making out bonds and mortgaging their property, the amount of wealth
in the world as a whole when at last they retired to bed would not be
greater by the tiniest fraction. If, then, to destroy all these
instruments is not to reduce the total amount of wealth in the world,
and if to create them is not to increase it, then clearly they are not
wealth. They are certificates of title. That is all. They are
documents which are evidence to the world of some right or title
vested in their owner. Clearly they are useless unless they can be
turned into bread and butter, turned into wealth. They are not in
themselves wealth.
To sum up: land is not wealth; labour is not wealth; slaves are not
wealth; and bank bills, mortgages, bonds and the ordinary coinage of
the realm are not wealth.
Before there can be wealth there must first be land. That land must
be worked upon by labour to produce the things by which man lives. Not
all the products of labour applied to land can, however, be classified
as "wealth". Regard must be paid to the thing produced. If
in some idle moment a man goes upon the seashore and makes some
mud-pies, not because he wants the mud-pies but simply for the
pleasure of making them, then the mud-pies he makes are clearly not
wealth. He does not want them - nobody wants them. If, on the other
hand, it is discovered that these particular mud-pies are good for the
complexion and are made for that reason, then clearly they are wanted;
they are wealth. In short, a distinction must be drawn between those
things which man makes but which, when made, gratify no one's desire,
and those things which do gratify someone's desire.
It is to be seen, therefore, that before an article can be wealth it
must satisfy three requirements. It must first have been land, must
then have been worked upon by labour and the product must gratify
human desire. The fact that the making of the thing gratified
someone's desire, as was the case with the mud-pies first mentioned,
does not make the product wealth. The product itself must gratify
human desire.
It of no consequence that the thing produced could not be sold,
provided that it does gratify someone's desire. Robinson Crusoe's
pallisade and cabin were wealth though there was no one to whom he
could have sold them. The notion that an article can only be wealth if
someone can be found who would buy it comes from the superficial
notion that economics is only concerned with the exchange of goods. In
truth, it makes no difference whether a man makes chairs for his own
use or whether he grows cabbages and buys the chairs with them. The
result is the same. The chairs are wealth.
"Wealth" may now be defined as land modified by labour so
as to fit it for the gratification of human desire.
CAPITAL
Wealth is made so that it may gratify human desire. Not all wealth,
however, is used for the immediate gratification of desire. Thus a
steam engine in a factory is wealth. It is land modified by labour so
as to fit it for the gratification of human desire. It is not,
however, used directly for this purpose as is the food on man's table.
Instead it is used to produce other things which in their turn will
meet a human want. In short, it is wealth used to produce more wealth.
Wealth so used, performs an economic function different from all other
wealth, and must therefore be put in a class by itself. This class
will, in this book, be called "capital". The distinction
between wealth which is capital and wealth which is not capital is one
of use. Thus a car used for pleasure is wealth being devoted to the
immediate gratification of desire. A car used in business is wealth
being used for the production of more wealth and is capital. It is
true that many forms of capital, such as a steam engine in a factory,
could not be very well used for any purpose except the production of
more wealth. But what matters is not the form which the wealth takes
but the use to which it is put.
To include in the factor called "capital" anything which is
not wealth is a mistake which leads to great confusion. By so doing,
things of different economic functions are confused with each other.
For example, land is not capital and can never be capital. Had there
been no land there would be no steam engine, but if there were no
steam engine, it certainly does not follow that there would be no
land. Again, if there were no labour, there would be no steam engine.
Land and labour must exist before it can come into existence. More
than that, if labour were not being constantly applied to land the
steam engine could not function. If miners were not daily winning the
coal from the earth to fire the furnaces, the steam engine could not
operate. If other miners were not boring the earth to obtain oil to
lubricate the engine's moving parts, it would soon seize up. If yet
others were not ploughing up the earth's surface to dig out the iron
ore to replace the engine's worn parts, its life would be short
indeed. Thus, capital is not merely brought into existence by the
application of labour to land, but is for the most part dependent upon
daily work upon the natural resources to keep it in operation.
Therefore, land must not be confused with capital, nor must labour,
skill or knowledge.
Still less should money or stocks and shares be called capital. They
are, as has already been said, mere evidence of title. Doubtless
accountants find it convenient to call money capital as for the
purpose of their profession everything is reduced to pounds or dollars
or as the case may be, but their figures are not capital. They can
trick with the figures - and many are deluded by them - but hard work
must create and maintain capital. The true nature of money and of
these titles to things will be discussed later in this book. It is
sufficient here to observe that they are not to be confused with the
stocks of grain, the herds of cattle, the coal, oil and machinery
which are capital when used to produce more wealth.
In this book "capital" will mean wealth used to produce
more wealth.
LAND, HUMAN DESIRES, LABOUR AND
WEALTH
As has been seen "Land" is all natural resources. Human
desires need no definition. "Labour" is all human effort. "Wealth"
is land modified by labour so as to fit it for the gratification of
human desire. "Capital" is wealth used to produce more
wealth.
The primary factors in social life are land, human desires and
labour. On them all else depends. Wealth is a secondary factor, being
itself produced by the primary factors. Capital is part of wealth. The
principles governing the relations between these economic factors are
universal and govern all social activity in the economic sphere.
As with wealth, great confusion of thought reigns over the question
of capital. Wealth having been defined in many current treatises as
anything having value, meaning thereby a market price, capital is
defined as anything that yields a revenue. Such a definition results
in bringing under the same head land which is let out at a rent, skill
and knowledge which procure incomes, mortgages and stocks and shares
and loans of money. In short, everything that is used in industry if
it brings a return to the owner, is lumped together as capital. The
very different nature of these things and the very different
principles which govern the return the owner obtains for them are thus
clouded over. Such confusion leads to the current use of vague and
indefinite terms such as "the capitalist system". Some,
seeing in this so-called "capitalist system" the exercise of
economic privilege and the exploitation of the many by the few,
inveigh against it. Others, seeing in the same system the opportunity
for enterprise and a reward for honest effort, rally to its support.
It is self-evident that the contending parties are not talking about
the same thing.
Upon a clear realization of the nature of the different factors in
operation and of the principles which govern and which have always
governed them, this confusion melts. Obviously the control of land
gives the owner very different powers from those acquired from the
power to work. The control of wealth gives yet different powers which
are deeply affected by the nature of wealth itself. To the control of
money still other powers belong. It is intended in this book to
examine the powers acquired by the owners of these very different
things and by the benefactors of other powers yet to be noticed. One
man may exercise powers as a landlord, powers as a labourer and powers
as a controller of wealth, and it will be necessary to assess the very
different results of these very different powers. The fact that one
man is at once landlord, labourer and controller of wealth must not be
allowed to hide the fact that he enjoys powers which are very
different in their economic strength and results. Some of the powers
he exercises may do harm, while other do good. To condemn him outright
is the action of blind envy. In no other sphere is it more important
than in social relationships that jealousy and malice should play no
part. The principles which should guide the student should be those of
justice, which are the principles governing the very nature of our
social relations.
It is relevant at this point to observe that the production of wealth
is not completed until the goods are in the hands of the ultimate
consumer. Thus when fish are hauled into the boat from the fishing
grounds of the ocean production has only just begun. It is not
complete when they are landed at the port, nor yet when they reach the
wholesaler's storehouse, nor again when they are sold in the market to
the retailer, nor even when they find there way into the housewife's
shopping basket, but only when cooked and served with some delicate
sauce they whet the appetite of some hungry mortal. The cooking and
serving are part of the production of wealth and the saucepans and
frying pans are capital. The housewife along with the merchants, the
retailers, the railway companies and the fishmongers are all concerned
in the production of wealth. Much of the production of wealth consists
only of the moving of a natural product from one place to another.
All the way from the coal face to the domestic grate the coal remains
the same in form, for its production is not only the winning of it
from the earth and the sifting of it from impurities but the
transportation of it to its ultimate destination. Thus the coal won
from the face by the hewer is wealth but its production is not
complete.
A few illustrations will serve well to sum up the important
differences between land, labour, wealth which is not capital, and
wealth which is used as capital. A herd of wild bison is land. Year in
and year out if undisturbed by man they continue in much the same
numbers for very considerable periods of time. A herd of cattle on a
farm is wealth. Unless they are constantly cared for, artificially
housed and protected from disease and natural enemies they will
quickly die off. The more highly cultivated they are the swifter is
this decay. In the same way a wild cherry tree is land. If undisturbed
by man wild fruit-trees in a wood maintain their numbers. The trees
which are cultivated in orchards, however, and which yield such
magnificent fruit need constant care and attention unless they are to
be blighted and to lose their fruitfulness. Both cattle and orchards,
being wealth used to produce more wealth, to yield beef or milk or
fruit, are capital. The domestic dog, however, or the flowering shrub
in the garden, not being used to produce more wealth is not capital.
RENT, WAGES AND INTEREST
Land, labour and wealth are for this purpose words of art and will be
used to describe the economic factors which have been defined.
Those who control one or other of these three factors may by means of
this control be empowered to claim a share of the wealth produced. For
each of these shares it will be necessary to use a technical term and
for this purpose the usual words will be used.
- Rent will be used to mean that share of
wealth which a man is able to obtain through his control of land.
- Wages will be used to mean that share of
wealth which a man is able to obtain through his control of his
own labour.
- Interest will be used to mean that share of
wealth which a man is able to command through his control of
wealth.
The full discussion of these avenues of distribution belongs to the
discussion of the distribution of wealth and will be postponed until
then.
|