What Should Georgists Do
To Achieve Success?
Hugh T.A. McGahan
[Reprinted from the International Union
Newsletter, February, 1970]
I agree with Fred Auld (International Union Newsletter, No.8). N).
Never was the world more in need of the remedy we can offer, but never
were we so ineffective in the counsels of government. If the proposals
of the Valuer-General of New Zealand now before our Parliament becomes
law, unimproved values legislation as we know it will disappear from
our Statute Book. That's where we have arrived after 80 years of
preaching!
The problem before us is to couch our remedy for the world's economic
and social ills in a language the ordinary people, the people who make
and break governments, can understand. Convince the ordinary man and
his wife that our remedy has something for them and we won't need to
split straws about what "rent" means. Convince the ordinary
man that we have the answer to his ever-continuing battle with rising
prices and we won't need to worry about the so-called intellectuals.
We should never forget that Henry George wrote Progress and
Poverty to find out why it was that in spite of increasing
productive power wages tended to give but a bare living. It was not to
make half-baked political economists. And the problem that George
concerned himself with is our problem today. Far too many of our
citizens live too close to the breadline for us to be complacent.
Another blunder has been to talk about the "land question."
We are not concerned with land at all. What concerns us is the public
revenue and its collection. Therefore, we should concentrate on the
taxation system and its reform.
The truth is that our governments don't know their business; we
single-taxers must teach, them. Gertainly no one else can. The
government, our agent, virtually gives to the site-holder a gift of
the value of those community services that governments are established
to carry out. But these community services cost money, and to get the
money necessary to pay for them governments resort to the taxing of
goods. Taxing of goods must| make the goods dearer. Worse still, the
amount imposed on goods represents a gift to a non-producing section
of the community.
All this is well illustrated in English history. Our modern system of
taxation dates from the imposition of the excise on beer and other
liquors by the Long Parliament in 1643. The old feudal dues had
certainly become oppressive, but the remedy was not their abolition
but changing to some form more suited to the altered circumstances, as
George pointed out in Progress and Poverty, Book VII, Chapter
4. Historians generally agree that the landowners of the time relieved
themselves of their financial responsibilities to the State and
transferred them to the wage-earners.
Disraeli wrote his book Sybil (1842) after two centuries'
experience with the system of taxing commodities in order to make a
gift to the site-owners on the "Golden Mile" in our cities
and towns. He said that "the principle of the system (the Dutch
system of finance) was to mortgage industry to protect property.
It
has made debt a national habit and has made credit the ruling power
a mortgaged aristocracy, a gambling foreign commerce, and a home trade
founded on morbid competition and a degraded people. Here too was
brought forth that monstrous conception which even patrician Borne
never equalled in its most ruthless period --. the mortgaging of
industry to protect property." Like a good politician, Disraeli
did nothing to correct the evil when he had the opportunity.
In our unimproved values legislation we have the answer for finding
the revenue necessary to maintain the State without increasing the
price of goods. Let us proclaim that from the housetops. Surely we
couldn't achieve less than we have after 80 years of trying to make
half-baked economists of well-meaning searchers after a better system
of wealth distribution.
|