The Pittsburgh Plan of Public Revenue
William Nissley McNair
[An address given at the 2nd Commerce and Finance
Luncheon of the St. Louis Extension of the Henry George School of
Social Science, 9 September, 1948]
I should like to start out with something we can all agree on,
whether we are business men or politicians, for we politicians have to
observe certain laws if we want to get along, just as do businessmen.
We seem to agree universally on this: The customer is always right.
The merchant who wants to increase his trade doesn't have a man at the
door to hit the customers on the head, nor does he have someone there
to pick their pockets before they come in to do their shopping. A good
merchant will do everything he can to increase the customer's
purchasing power.
Your Customers Are Being Robbed!
Businessmen would do well to concern themselves with what they are
doing, through the Federal government, to impoverish their customers.
Do you realize that you are actually electing men to office to pick
the pockets of your customers? They not only do that, but they slap a
mortgage on the old homestead before the customer gets down to the
store. In what condition does that leave him to do any buying at your
place of business? After the Civil War the federal debt per family was
$400. After the first world war it was $1100 per family. Now the
federal debt averages $7,000 for every family in the country. If that
ever sinks into your customers' heads, you'll find them in a poor
state of mind to do any business. These debts, remember, are a first
lien on production.
I want to suggest today a method by which you can relieve your
customers of some of this distress and get commerce and finance on a
sound basis so that we can have steady good times.
Are You Collecting Your Bills?
The second fundamental law of business I want to mention is this: You
have got to collect your bills. You have to collect them for yourself.
You can't let some outsider go around among your customers picking up
their money and sticking it in his pockets. I can tell you that
Pittsburgh does not collect its bills. This fact I learned while
serving as Mayor of Pittsburgh and as a member of the State
Legislature of Pennsylvania. Much of the city's earnings is going into
the pockets of a few families. I don't know much about the city of St.
Louis, but if this city, or any other, were doing differently, I think
I would have seen it in the newspaper headlines.
Now the sole function of the mechanism which we call municipal
government is the furnishing of services such as police protection,
fire protection, sewage, garbage and rubbish removal to certain
trading locations. Then it forces the users of these services to pay
the market rate of the value of these services as land rent to the
holders of the sites. The municipality then goes after the taxpayers
for the maintenance of the city equipment and the money to meet the
payroll, instead of collecting the city's earnings, expressed in the
values of these land sites, and using such earnings to keep up the
city.
I read in a Chicago paper the notice of the sale of a building. The
lot didn't enter into the transaction at all. The site had two leases,
one for $24,000 a year for the vacant lot when the building was built
in 1893, another for $30,000 some twenty years later. What are these
two charges amounting to $54,000 a year that every customer must help
pay before he walks out of the building? This is the market price
fixed by the demand for the city services in these land sites, none of
which was furnished by the owners of the sites who get the money.
The city should collect its earnings even if it has to abolish all
its taxes to do so. We've started to do that very thing in Pittsburgh.
We are recapturing some of Pittsburgh's earnings brought about by our
transportation system that dumps thousands of customers an hour in
front of these business locations. We've started sending out some
bills for furnishing services there by putting a heavy tax on the
value of these sites. At the same time we have cut the tax rate on
buildings fifty percent.
Meeting the Housing Shortage
We've had this system in effect now for some thirty years. It has
done much to encourage building, although Pittsburgh, like every other
city today, has a housing shortage due largely to the shortage of
building materials. Of course, the only way to solve a housing
shortage is to build more houses. The only person to solve this
problem is the speculative builder or the private individual who has
saved enough money to build a home.
As I go around St. Louis I find there are plenty of good locations
for housing projects or for individual homes, but they are standing
idle. What discourages people from building on these convenient spots
so well supplied with all the facilities necessary for comfortable
homes? Might it not be the fact that if anybody did build on these
vacant lots, he would have to pay a heavy tax on the building until it
was torn down or burnt up? As long as the site is held idle, the owner
has low taxes. As soon as he starts building, he is discouraged by
high building taxes. I therefore think it might be well for your city
to study our plan with the idea that it would encourage more building
if St. Louis would also reduce taxes on improvements.
In Pittsburgh we would like to take all the taxes off buildings. But
until that time comes we feel we are offering some inducement to
builders by giving them a lower tax rate on their improvements. This
has another effect which we are noticing in our city. When you cut the
tax rate on houses you will have to raise the tax rate on land values
in order to get sufficient revenue to run the city. So today our tax
on land values is $28 a thousand and our rate on buildings is
one-half, or $14 a thousand. We notice that this rate of $28 a
thousand on the land values is bringing more locations on the market
at a more reasonable price. This in turn makes it easier to carry on a
building project because the initial outlay is lower.
Put yourself in the place of a speculator who has a large area of
vacant land ripe for development. If his taxes are low he can hold on
until he gets a high price. So the land remains idle. The builder is
unable to go ahead with his project because he can't get a site on
which to build. When the taxes on the land values are raised, as they
were in Pittsburgh, the speculator is forced to let go. And the land
comes on the market at reasonable prices so that the builder may go
ahead with his enterprise.
How Pittsburgh Untaxed Industry.
We applied the same theory to industry in Pittsburgh many years ago
by exempting all raw materials, finished products, and machinery from
taxation. I am informed, that you still tax this form of industry in
St. Louis. I would suggest that you exempt machinery, raw materials
and equipment in your city, even though it raises the tax on land
values. We have found in Pittsburgh that a high land value tax does
not harm anyone except the land speculator who is holding back
production. Even he will be benefited if he will put his land to
proper use. Land that is put to use, either for housing or for
industry, can well afford to pay a higher tax if buildings and
equipment are tax exempt.
Housing and industry must have public conveniences. These are
furnished by the government and the government should collect their
cost from the land site benefited by them. To the extent the
speculative lot holder is not taxed, he too can collect a charge for
these services before the builder can get the site. This leaves a
smaller amount that can be paid the worker in the shape of wages. If
the city checks this land speculation by collecting more of the value
its own services generate, which expresses itself in the value of the
land site, as we do in Pittsburgh, then the workers can be untaxed on
their wages and, as customers, have more to spend with the merchants
and the industries that supply them.
Although we cannot claim great results from the step we have taken,
we do say that it is a more logical and reasonable system of raising
revenue for a metropolitan center. In a way it is an experiment. We
put it into practice back in 1913. It is now no longer just in the
realm of theory, but accepted practice in tax matters. It has shifted
about $3,000,000 of our tax burden from the pockets of many thousand
small home owners and building operators on to a few old family
estates and speculating individuals and corporations holding
speculative sites.
Recently one of our old families has thrown all of its vacant lots on
the market. These are now in the hands of builders who are waiting for
the supply of building materials to come on the market to improve
these locations. There is no doubt in my mind that this higher tax on
land values was the thing that induced this family to allow its
holdings to go on the market.
The Pittsburgh Plan in St. Louis
How can St. Louis adopt this system? First, I would suggest that you
send a committee to Pittsburgh to study our plan of lower taxes on
buildings and check its results, and also our method of applying the
system. Next you should simplify your tax set-up and limit your tax
base to land and buildings. You will probably find the assessed value
of your land going down as has been the case in Pittsburgh, so that
you cannot hesitate about raising the tax rate, since you must have
the same amount of money to run your city.
In order to get public support for this change, you may have to do a
lot of educational work to sell the voters the idea that it does make
a difference what we tax. We found when we first started this movement
that people said, "What difference does it make what you tax? You
must get the same amount of revenue to run the government." We
had to convince the voters that a tax on buildings would discourage
new construction whereas a tax on land values would encourage the use
of locations for improvements.
When I sat in the office of Mayor of Pittsburgh, it was my job to
furnish various parts of the city with various services. Among these
services was police protection, fire protection, removal of sewage and
garbage, furnishing pure water, cleaning the streets and a thousand
and one things that go to make up a civilized community. The same
thing is true of St. Louis. Here, as in Pittsburgh, various parts of
the city receive all these community conveniences, but some parts
receive more than others, especially business sections.
Here your streets and traffic arteries converge, unloading every day
thousands of customers on downtown corners that merchants bid up to
fabulous figures. In order to get the advantage of these aids to
business, you must secure exclusive possession of such a corner. Now
our argument in Pittsburgh is this; Those who hold these corners and
charge high prices for their use are really selling the services
furnished by the city. They should pay to keep up equipment used by
the city, help to maintain its plant, and help to meet the cost of the
payroll of the firemen, the policemen, and other city servants.
If you recapture more of what the city spends building up land
values, I do not think the holders of these locations will make any
complaint. They will realize that it is right and just that the city
should maintain these facilities and conditions that make their return
on their property so valuable. On the other hand, when you increase
the city revenue from these locations, you will be able to reduce the
burden on the home owner and the producer. This will be of general
benefit to the community.
Community Earnings Versus Taxation on Production.
After all, these community advantages that I've been talking about
are due to the services furnished by the city. The federal government
and the state government have very little to do with it. And yet their
exactions are far greater than those demanded by our city authorities.
The tremendous proportion of our production that goes to pay our
income taxes is largely frittered away in maintaining useless bureaus
that don't add a penny to the wages or site values of our cities. But
Congress could fire two-thirds of the employees in Washington, and the
value of land in St. Louis wouldn't be decreased a cent.
Our research bureaus are furnishing us daily with graphs which show
the business cycle and show the rise of speculation in farm prices and
business sites in the city. They tell us that when they reach a
certain height we'll crack, just as we did every time before. We take
our lessons from that and prevent speculation in these locations which
are merely the capitalized value of community earnings (land rent)
that are bought and sold by the siteholders. We could avoid this boom
and bust if our community would say: "We're going to use this
income to maintain our equipment and meet our payrolls. We are not
going to let anyone misappropriate the people's natural income and
force us to tax, directly or indirectly, the income of workers who
make up the great bulk of consumer spenders."
So I say again, there are two principles we must observe: you can't
treat your customers rough, and you must collect your bills yourself.
You often hear the plea that business men should get into politics.
But what good can they do in government if they haven't the
fundamental training in economics? They should also support an
educational movement that will raise the economic understanding and
awareness of the majority of the people. The Henry George School of
Social Science treats these problems from a scientific standpoint. It
approaches problems in a scientific manner, getting at facts which bar
prejudice, mistakes of custom, and highly selfish wishes in the
people's economic matters. After all, commerce and finance must not be
handicapped. We must get rid of unnecessary and unnatural restrictions
if our free democratic way of life is to endure. And to accomplish all
this we must first have right thinking from which right action will
follow.
|