What's Wrong With Land Value Taxation?
Dick Netzer
[A paper presented under the Henry George Research
Program,
Pace University, New York, 4 November 1982]
I think my topic was meant to be provocative, and I hope it will be.
I will not deliver a learned address, nor go back to the writings of
Henry George to discuss the topic of land value taxation. Instead I
start with the premise that in fact there really isn't very much wrong
with land value taxation in concept. I want to talk about the issues
in current context; the context, that is, of the United States, in the
1980's -- a basically urban society.
Now urban economists, more than mainstream economists, tend to agree
with the proposition that land value taxation is both equitable and
efficient. In fact, a fair number of urban economists now subscribe to
the proposition that the only appropriate way to efficiently finance
local governments in a society such as ours is by a combination of
land value taxation and user charges for services that have
identifiable beneficiaries and therefore can be appropriately financed
through some kind of public pricing. The question then is, if the land
value tax is ideal, and if it has been persuasively advocated, with
the kind of eloquence you find in the works of Henry George, why is
land value taxation for all practical purposes absent from the United
States?
I know that there are a few isolated cases in this country where
there is some form of land value taxation. But, by and large we live
in a country which has decisively and repeatedly over the years
rejected land value taxation as the mode of finance of any level of
government, including local governments. In fact, the country has
decisively rejected even the idea of taxing land values equally with
buildings. We have differentially heavy taxation of improvements in
almost every jurisdiction in the United States, the opposite of what I
think most people here would prescribe. There has to be something
wrong with land value taxation in some way, conceptually or
practically, otherwise it surely would have been more widely adopted
by now.
After some searching for the answer to this paradox, l think I have
finally found it. The answer starts with a rather fundamental change
in the perception of what is appropriate, what is fair, what is moral
in taxation between the nineteenth century and today. We live now in a
climate of opinion where the taxation of wealth as such, rather than
income or expenditure, is basically considered wrong by most people.
That was not true in the nineteenth century when Henry George wrote.
The issue that he was addressing is -- shall we tax wealth that is
created by man or shall we tax personal wealth that is generated by
land rents? But, the problem we are dealing with now is the perception
that the taxation of wealth is wrong, no matter how that wealth is
generated.
But, in the nineteenth century taxation of wealth was considered a
pretty good idea -- the only taxation that existed in the United
States at the time was state and local property taxes, (aside from
import duties and taxes on alcoholic beverages) and these were
justified as taxes on all forms of wealth. If my analysis is right,
then there was some point at which the change in perception occurred.
How did this come about? In large part the change, like so many other
things that we see in this country in the 1980's, is yet another one
of the legacies of the Great Depression. The Great Depression was
preceded by a twenty-odd year period in which there was a very
substantial increase in levels of property taxation in the United
States associated with rapid urbanization and big increases in public
expenditures.
In the thirties, as we know, there was a collapse in property values,
as well as in income. And, in the early thirties, of course, the local
governments did not conclude that there was no wealth left to tax.
Instead, they observed the ostensible taxable wealth on the assessment
rolls and extended taxes against that ostensible wealth. Of course,
there were huge delinquencies, among farmers and among the large
numbers of people with modest income who in the 1920's had become home
owners. The results were aggressive movements in a number of states
during that period to limit property taxes. In Florida there was a
state referendum, which was defeated by a whisker, which would have
abolished the property tax totally in that state.
The property tax subsequently was reprieved by rising real incomes.
But in prosperity these were the seeds of serious political problems.
During the fifteen years ending in 1981, there was an especially rapid
rise in housing values, in a country now overwhelmingly dominated by
owner-occupants of housing. This rapid run up in property values was
far in excess of the increase in incomes. It produced vast unrealized
capital gains, that is gains on the value of the houses owned by
people who had not sold them or had no intention of selling them, but
who had huge gains on paper.
I believe that a considerable factor in the whole so-called revolt
against property taxes in the United States in the 1970's came from
the taxation of unrealized capital gains, particularly homeowners1
unrealized capital gains. I think that Americans consider such
taxation inequitable, harsh and entirely illegitimate with respect to
owner-occupied housing. The size of the unrealized capital gains in
the 1970's was really vast. I have made some estimates of the size of
the increase in the value of existing unsold, unchanged, unaltered
owner-occupied non-farm houses between 1969 and 1979. The total
estimated increase in market value of owner-occupied housing
(including land) between 1969 and 1979 was about $1,500 billion from
roughly $650 billion to $2.2 trillion. Of that $1,500 billion
increase, about $600 billion, about forty percent of the increase, was
in the form of unrealized capital gains. More than 25 percent of the
market value of owner-occupied housing, as of 1979, consisted of
unrealized capital gains, of houses many of which people had lived in
for many years and had no intention of ever selling. The very rapid
run up in property values is fairly obviously associated with
inflation, with the income tax preferences attached to owner occupied
housing, and with the fact that, until 1979. there were negative real
rates of interest on home mortgages.
But this by itself should not have caused negative reactions by
taxpayers: taxpayers are concerned with actual tax bills, not the way
in which they are calculated. Why should there have been large
increases in tax bills? If property values were increasing very
rapidly, much more rapidly than income, even more rapidly than rate of
inflation in general, effective tax should have declined and actual
tax liabilities for many property owners might not have increased very
much at all. Tax liabilities might in some cases have actually
increased by less than earned income.
In reality what happened was that many local governments were
cheating. They used the increase in market values during this period,
in many cases, to expand local government expenditure at rapid rates.
Moreover, the situation was aggravated in those states where the
property tax assessment system was reformed, with revaluations because
of changes in state law and court decisions. This happened in the
state of Massachusetts, where there were numerous increases in
assessed values in many parts of the state during the 60's and 70's
because there were revaluations going on even as market values rose
rapidly. Local governments took advantage of this. They cut their tax
rates by substantially less than assessed property values rose and
expanded local government expenditures.
This happened spectacularly in California, where house values are
higher than anywhere else in the country. So property tax bills in
dollar terms rose very rapidly for many owners of existing unchanged
property. Voters considered this illegitimate. In close to half the
states, during the years between 1970 and 1980. voters through
referenda or through legislatures put effective property limits on tax
levies as well as on tax rates. Legislatures also enacted a variety of
other kinds of tax preference arrangements, for farm land, for the
elderly and for other purposes. I view much of this as a strong
reaction against the notion that it is legitimate to tax wealth, if
that wealth is in the form of unrealized capital gains.
Now the relevance of this to land value taxation is obvious. Land
value, by definition, is taxation of a form of wealth, and it
necessarily involves taxation of unrealized capital gains. Henry
George told us, eloquently, of the appropriation of the increase in
productivity of labor and capital by passive land owners, who sit put,
hang on, and realize their capital gains many years later. It's an
inherent characteristic of land value taxation to tax unrealized
capital gains. It would defeat some of the very real advantages of
land value taxation to substitute for annual taxation of capitalized
land rents such alternatives as land value increment taxes on land
that is sold, or other taxes triggered by transfers. That tends to
discourage transfers, to reduce the fluidity of the market and rewards
the land hoarder.
Those of you who are convinced Georgists have no problem with the
concept of taxation of unrealized taxable gains in this form. Neither
do most economists. Most economists think that wealth is wealth, and
the fact that it hasn't been realized by sale doesn't mean anything at
all. You can borrow against that wealth. You can consume on the basis
of having that extra wealth. But I think we are peculiar. Our fellow
Americans do have a problem with the concept of taxation and
unrealized capital gains, and we have to worry how to overcome that
problem.
Now it is possible that changes in the external circumstances will
help. The decade of the 1970's was a freakish one, I believe. We are
not likely to see the kind of capital gains in housing values that we
had in the 70's again. It is almost impossible to imagine a scenario
in which there are negative real rates of interest on home mortgages
(except very temporarily) ever again in American society. So huge
unrealized gains are implausible. That should reduce hostility to land
value taxation. On the other hand, there are numerous American cities
in economic difficulty; in real terms, the market value of taxable
property in those places declines faster than real income declines. In
such circumstances, stiff taxes based on the value of land are not
likely to be acceptable, especially since some of the precipitously
declining land values are those of the land underlying owner-occupied
housing.
I do not think we can count on ready public acceptance of land value
taxation even if the 1980's are unlike the 1970's. I don't have any
real solutions to the problems I have posed. Most Americans think that
land value taxation is in essence unjust, not because they see land
value taxation itself as being unjust, but because it is a form of
taxation of wealth in the form of unrealized capital gains. I think it
is proper to face this problem head on, which has not been done.
Instead, advocates of land value taxation wax eloquent about the
wondrous consequences for us collectively of switching to a tax that
is in reality feared and loathed by most American voters as
individuals.
What's wrong with land value taxation, in my view, is that the
advocates have yet to find ways to persuade ordinary Americans that
their conception of tax justice is just plain wrong. Economists have
nothing to offer here. We need some exceedingly persuasive moral
philosophers. Perhaps what we need is the Henry George who can address
Americans as they are now, in the circumstances in which they find
themselves, and with their beliefs as they are in the 1980's.
|