The Land Tax and Inflation
Knud Tholstrup
[A paper delivered at the 1979 Joint Georgist
Conference, San Francisco, California. Slightly condensed from the
original to exclude two charts of data]
In Land and Liberty, January/February, 1979 issue, Anthony
Carter wrote,
"The background for writing Progress and Poverty
was that Henry George was perplexed as to why, in an age of plenty,
there was so much depravation. He set out to analyze this paradox,
and identify the reasons for it, and having done so to propose a
remedy. His remedy was to abolish all taxes except that on the value
of land ..."
And on this point he is backed by Milton Friedman, who ninety-nine
years later, in November 1978, said,
"There is a sense in which all taxes are
antagonistic to free enterprise -- and yet we need taxes.... So the
question is, which are the least bad taxes? In my opinion the least
bad tax is the property tax on the unimproved value of land, the
Henry George argument of many, many years ago."
To my mind, there is no technical problem in converting income taxes
to taxing of land value, LVT.
We agree that poverty, in spite of progress, still is a world-wide
problem. The problem is to convince people, and thus the leading
politicians, about the urgency of starting that conversion just now.
It is ridiculous that the ideas of Henry George have not been able to
penetrate the minds of both layman and economists. To my mind they are
with cheap explanations, such as Marxism. It is easy for a poor man to
understand that he shall share the accumulated wealth with the rich: "When
all people are equal, they should have an equal right to all the food,
clothing, and so forth".
But for too many years, Marxism has been the religion of poor people,
and unscrupulous politicians and economists to benefit from those easy
arguments, so they could still have a free ride on the backs of
labouring people.
Just look at the examples from Eastern Europe, where the top
politicians are collecting a many times higher salary than the wages
for the low-income brackets, than in the Western world. In my own
country, the top manager will probably earn 4 times as much as the
common wage-earner, but only 2-3 times as much after tax, while the
Eastern proportion, including fringe-benefits, easily runs up to 10
times as much as labour.
If you would distribute to other tax-payers what the most rich two
percent earn above average (after taxes), the ninety-eight per cent
would get only one week's extra income in a year, but already next
year the amount will have shrunk to next to nothing, as all initiative
will be killed when the carrot is snatched away, and all the fun about
being a private enterpriser is gone.
The Chairman of the biggest bank in Scandinavia when visiting
Copenhagen recently, said,
"Taxation in Sweden is a most advanced system,
practising taking from one and giving to another, so that both give
up working." (income levelling).
In Sweden, surplus income is taxed by 8870 In a board meeting in
Sweden last May we decided to index the salary of our manager by
100.000 Swedish kr. (=$25.000) in order to give him a rise of 12.000
SW.Kr.($3.000)
Up to 1914, Great Britain was the leading industrial country in
Europe -- first in technology and living standard, after a long period
with considerable property taxes and practically no tax on income. But
she was also first in introducing the-next-to-confiscation of surplus
incomes 40 years before Sweden. Surplus income was taxed 95%, today
83%, and on unearned incomes if any there is a surtax from 10 to 15%
on top of the 83%, which consequently Mrs. Thatcher has now decided to
reduce to 60%.
Since then, G.B. has suffered from two wars, but it is more due to
suffering from "income confiscation" that G.B. today is far
behind all North European countries.
This tax system would have ruined Great Britain completely if she had
not found the North Sea full of oil.
As a free enterpriser, I believe in three fundamental laws: land
value taxation, free trade, and free enterprise.
And I have good reasons for the latter when I observe the development
in Scandinavia against that in Russia.
In my youth, many poor Swedes settled in Denmark because Sweden was a
very poor country 60 years ago, and so was Finland. Today, Sweden is
paying the highest salaries in Europe, alternating with Denmark.
In Finland, they have a living standard 3 times as high as in
European Russia. But Finland was one of the poorest provinces of
Russia until 1917. Most of the country is covered by snow and ice half
the year. Even though Russia has plenty of first-clas farm land, she
is not self-supplying. The only free enterprisers are the wives of the
farmhands with a small garden. They supply the market with 307o of all
the food, grown on 2-3% of all the land.
Michael V. Rodriguez, founder-president of the British Institute of
Inventors, says (I quote:)
"Most people see that Marxism does not work. It does
not redistribute the earnings made by capital. It subsumes them. It
digests them. It eliminates them."
J.K. Galbraith said in 1977 that "..Poverty is painful. It would
be good if we knew the source of it." (quoted from a Danish
newspaper).
By being a Georgist for more than 50 years, and with the natural
understanding of practical matters, such as
(1) "All improvements are ending up in higher land prices"
and
(2) "All costs are ending up in higher consumer prices",
I had a good background for observing this source. It is very simple:
When some people are able to make incomes without producing work,
there must be other people who are getting too little for their work;
and that is just the picture of inflation, with its two sides:
consumers pay rising prices to balance the rising land prices. So the
answer to Mr. Galbraith must be:
There are several sources, but inflation is regarded as
one of the main sources, and the severest.
In other words, your first aim must be to stop inflation, and to do
that, you must find the explanation and the source of it. And the
efforts have to be done, as inflation is regarded from many sides as
the severest economic evil in our time, which is deepening out the gap
between the rich industrial countries and the poor
development-countries, and thus responsible for the lack of stability
in both places, as prices for industrial products are rising in
proportion with inflation, long before the raw materials from the poor
countries increase in price, and poor countries are coming trailing
behind and will never catch up before inflation is stopped.
In industrial countries, the lack of stability causes failing
employment, political stirring, and violence, as a consequence of the
fact that employees are trailing along behind the price development.
Even when wages are regulated after the price index the regulation
always takes place after prices have risen. That is one of the reasons
for not blaming rising salaries for inflation; it is the other way
round: the salaries have to rise to meet the rising prices.
It could best be illustrated by a staircase, the bannister of which
is the rising prices, and the steps are the salary indexing:
Staircase with bannister (prices) and steps (wage level)
[Image Not Available in this online version]
-- Triangles below dotted line being compensated later on
by productivity-based wage-increases or/and other wage increases --
It is easy to see that labour are not getting paid in time for the
triangles in between by indexing Only.
We must not forget that the purpose of production is consumption, and
there must be a market for the products. If this market is ignored,
you have unemployment, trouble and unrest in the working places.
It is also responsible for the two followers: the high level of
interest, and the lacking balance in foreign exchange.
Declining value of the coin accelerates the hedging against inflation
by investing in real estate and the willingness to pay high interest
for a loan to finance the purchase. The high interest is increasing
the costs of production altogether, thus contributing to the
inflation.
Efforts of wage control and price stop have shown to be of very
little effect to inflation. Instead, it hampers the very production
and creates unemployment. - The recipe has proved wrong.
In their efforts to tackle inflation, governments are only doing
patchwork because they are tackling the effects instead of the reason,
not realizing that inflation has two sides: winners and losers. The
same thing is expressed in Henry Hazlitt's book Inflation"
from 1964, under the heading "Inflation has Two Faces".
I quote:
"All those who gain through inflation on net
balance, necessarily do so at the expense of others who lose through
it on net balance".
Winners are those who get the windfall of land value rising, and the
losers are those who pay rising prices for their consumption.
The stopping of inflation must start by stopping the winners from
collecting the community-created land value rising, and that can only
be done by putting a levy on land value, so that the rising value will
give a rising rent to the community^ to be used for reduction of
income - (and other) taxes, thus creating a balance between the rising
rent and the declining of the taxes, so what people pay more as
tenants, they save as taxpayers.
No surplus of purchasing power to press up prices.--
To understand inflation in money, you must have a clear
picture of the consistence of money.
In his book, Money - whence it came, and where it went, 1975,
John Kenneth Galbraith said that until 1933, economists regarded only
coins and bank notes as "money", but since 1933, check
accounts were included, as for payment there is no difference between
a heap of notes and a check for the same amount, they are both equally
valid payment media. And that is what we today call "M 1".
Later this was enlarged to comprise all bank deposits, now called "M
2", and today we operate with up to M 5, according to the Staff
Papers from the United States' Board of Governors of the Federal
Reserve System, with the title "Improving the Monetary Aggregates",
published in November, 1978. "M 3" includes credit union
shares and other loan shares.
Learning that, I wrote to Mr. William Miller of the Federal Reserve
Board, asking, Why don't you include all papers with an IOU? and got
his reply January, 1979 (I quote): "
Your suggestions for
redefining the money supply come at a timely moment.
"
1973, Milton Friedman paid a visit to Copenhagen, on which occasion I
discussed the cause of inflation with him, and stated that we have
inflation when the money supply is rising faster than production. But
he would not accept my explanation, nor my statement that the only
major source of excess money supply was from land value rising,
collected by private people without giving anything in return. I am
therefore happy to read that he now says that "We have inflation
when the amount of money increases faster than the increase of
production", but still not giving the right explanation from
where it comes. And that also accounts for Mr. Hazlitt, who correctly
says, "It is impossible to bring prices down by increasing
production, if the money supply is being increased even faster",
but also he fails to explain the main source of the excess money
supply.
When Milton Friedman last visited Copenhagen in 1978, I again
discussed the cause of inflation with him, but he refused to accept my
definition of money and is still blaming the federal banks for issuing
too much money, in which he is incorrect, as the federal banks work
along the same lines as all other banks, they can only lend money in
the same amount as depositors save up, except for issuing the amount
of bank notes you and I like to carry in our wallets, and the cashiers
need for daily change. The amount of circulating notes is not of any
importance. It is only about 2 pet of the total amount of purchasing
media as defined by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System, and the increase in a year is only 1% of the total increase of
M 3.
I would like to give you some figures from Denmark.
The amount of bank notes here has shrunk from 5% to well over 2% of
the total amount of circulating payment media over the last 10 years.
To issue a mortgage deed is actually to issue money of your own. When
land is sold, it is paid by maybe three kinds of money: a check from a
depositor, a handful of bonds, and for the remainder a mortgage deed
issued on the land; and this mortgage deed is as good cash as any
other kind of money. The seller who receives it can now use it for his
investments, or just put it aside and collect the annual interest
yielding from it (indeed unearned income).
If you try to control economy by putting restrictions upon bank loans
(depositors' money), or on the amount of bonds issued, the amount of
mortgage deeds will, according to Danish experiences, rise just enough
to make the balance, as trade in real estate will never stop.
I have the understanding that this is also the case in United States,
where you will also find financing when needed, and are willing to pay
any interest demanded, which is also the reason for the present high
level of interest.
As my feeling was that figures in United States and Denmark are
proportionally very similar, I was not astonished to read the
following remarks by Fred Harrison in Land and Liberty, March/April
1979:
"Since 1949 the Consumer Price Index (CPI) has risen
nearly 300%. The cost of a typical new single-family home has risen
by over 500%. The fastest-growing element in the price of houses is
land - which rose by 1.275%.
"Land prices now constitute 257* of the total cost of a
typical home, up from 11% in 1949. During this period, labour and
material costs fell from 69% to 47%". (= of the total)
This means that land value in the US has risen about 250 billion $
last year, and there US. will find its source of inflation. You cannot
avoid the rise, but if collected and used for the reduction of taxes,
the value rising will be neutralized, and there will be no
inflationary effect: What people pay more in rent they will pay less
in taxes, instead of an addition on consumer prices.
How to do that, I am explaining in another paper, "How to
Convert Income Tax Into LVT".
When, 30 years ago, I set up my theory in Denmark, it was not easy
for me to gain understanding, even from the Georgists. But I think I
am in full agreement with Henry George himself who says on page 40 in
the 4th edition of "Progress and Poverty",
"Increase in the amount of bonds, mortgages, notes,
or bank bills cannot increase the wealth of the community that
includes as well those who promise to pay as those who are entitled
to receive. The enslavement of a part of their number could not
increase the wealth of a people, for what the enslavers gained the
enslaved would lose.
"Increase in land value does not represent increase in the
common wealth, for what landowners gain by higher prices, the
tenants or purchasers who must pay them will lose."
- A good illustration of the two sides of inflation. The tenants and
purchasers necessarily have to obtain higher prices for their service
and products in order to pay the increasing rent. Rent is a
considerable cost on production, and will, as all other costs, end up
in inflated prices on goods.
Even though it is 100 years ago Henry George wrote (p, 268),
"That land speculation is the true cause of
industrial depression is, in the United States, clearly evident. In
each period of industrial activity land values have steadily risen,
culminating in speculation which carried them up in great jumps.
This has been invariably followed by a partial cessation of
production, and its correlative, a cessation of effective demand
(dull trade), generally accompanied by a commercial crash; and then
has succeeded a period of comparative stagnation, during which the
equilibrium has been again slowly established, and the same round
been run again. This relation is observable throughout the civilized
world. Periods of industrial activity always culminate in a
speculative advance of land values, followed by symptoms of checked
production, generally shown at first by cessation of demand from the
newer countries, where the advance in land values has been greatest",
it could as well have been written yesterday. And I am underlining
his remarks on page 413:
"Taxes may be imposed upon the value of land until
all rent is taken by the State, without reducing the wages of labor
or the reward of capital one iota; without increasing the price of a
single commodity, or making production in any way more difficult."
You could conclude the opposite way: that failing to increase LVT
will reduce wages and profit, increase consumer prices (inflation) and
make production in every way more difficult.
What Henry George is doing here is actually, in short explaining the
nature and the cure of inflation, which of course will disappear when
all land rent is collected.
As also stressed in Henry George's own preface to the 4th edition of
P&P, page XV,
"It is seen that private property in land, instead
of being necessary to its improvement and use, stands in the way of
improvement and use, and entails an enormous waste of productive
forces; that the recognition of the common right to land involves no
shock or dispossession, but is to be reached by the simple and easy
method of abolishing all taxation save that upon land values. And
this an inquiry into the principles of taxation shows to be, in all
respects, the best subject of taxation." -
It must be evident that this LVT should replace other taxes, but I
think we have to stress that this can be done without violating the
right to private land property.
In 1957-60, my theory was proven to be true. After being re-elected,
Justice party, the Georgists, came into a key position between Left
and Right, after gaining three more seats in Parliament. As the
minister of finance in the former Social Demokrat government had a
good understanding of the Georgist ideas, I approached him and
suggested forming a three-party coalition between the Social Demokrats
(corresponding to Labour party in Great Britain) and another Liberal
party (corresponding to the Liberal in Great Britain). Collecting the
land rent was to be the main point of the government.
As soon as this government was established, land speculation stopped;
and so did inflation. In the following 3% years, inflation was only 1%
average, against 5% annually before and after that period, and further
rising since then.
The rate of interest fell, so in 1958-59 it was less than half of
what it is today.
Unemployment eased off, the jobs increased by 100,000 (equal to 4
million new jobs in US, as the total number of Americans is 42 times
that of the Danes).
The deficit in balance of payment was changed into a surplus in a few
months. Foreign debts were reduced by 75 percent during that period,
and no new taxes were introduced in a few cases even reductions took
place.
The annual polls showed the highest degree of satisfied voters ever,
with the result that we had practically no strikes during the period
at all, and industry was able to pay rising wages, so the labour had
the highest rise in real income that was ever experienced.
Observing the improving development, I resigned from Parliament in
1958, after 12 years' service taking more and more of my time, leaving
too little time for my own growing business.
The economic effects of the cessation of land speculation were
astounding and aroused much attention far beyond the borders of my
country. On the 2nd October, 1960, the New York Times wrote "Big
lesson from a small nation", and Professor Commager recommended
that other nations might learn from Denmark's example.
But those who used to benefit from the inflation and land speculation
started a campaign against the Georgists, and used the highest amount
of money ever used in any campaign, directed against our small party,
so that by next election in 1960 we came below the minimum limit for
representation in Parliament, and presently the new laws concerning
the collecting of land value rising were abolished again. And today
our country is suffering from the same illnesses as other countries:
high unemployment -- high inflation - high foreign debts -- heavy
taxes -- angry labour - and accelerating land prices.
As you may know, in Denmark we have a public land valuation every
four years, and running statistics about sales prices for land.
(Annual valuation is under consideration). In the four-year period
from 1973 to 77, the value rose from 103 billion DKr. to 197 billion,
and at an accelerating speed, so the rise in the last year was at
least 30 billion DKr., or 5.5 billion in US$. And I am practically
sure that the value of all the land in US, with 42 times the Danish
population, has risen correspondingly, last year 225 billion US$.
Through studying newspapers and periodicals, I have made the
observation that there is a close connection between the building
activity in a country and the present inflation. Accelerating building
activity is also accelerating the demand for land, and thus causing
rising prices for a building plot. When American economists expects a
price rise in 1978 of 6 percent, I wrote to "Fortune" and "U.S.
News & World Report" and to Mr. Milton Friedman, who later
agreed with me, that the inflation would be higher, as U.S. was
experiencing a strongly accelerating building activity (2 million
homes). I was right, as inflation was at least two percent higher than
estimated. (Actually, it reached 9,9%).
As I now learn that there will be built 10-12 percent fewer homes
this year than in 1978, I should not wonder if the inflation would
decline again in second half of this year, after the acceleration in
the early spring, so that the inflation after all would not be much
higher this year than last year in the US. We will see!
It is evident that there is a link between the demand for building
plots and the inflation. In Switzerland they had a moderate inflation
up to 1970. But as the great migration of foreign workers made shelter
necessary, building activity was speeded up and rose from 50.000 to
80.000 homes in 1973. In the same year, inflation soared to 11.9
percent, twice as high as in 1970.
This migration stopped because of general cautiousness due to the oil
embargo in 1972 and today the building of new homes does not exceed a
30.000. Inflation 1977 was only 1,3%.
The rising building activity had an enormous increasing effect on
land prices, but since 1973 land prices have practically not risen at
all.
It is of particular interest that this occurred in the country of
Switzerland, which in spite of high wages had no unemployment, no
deficit on the balance of payment (the contrary), no increase in
taxes, and no deficit on the budget, all four of which in other
countries are commonly blamed by the economists for causing the
inflation. And yet, Switzerland had almost 12 percent inflation in
1973 (34 percent up from 1970 to 1973).
That there is a connection between land value rising and inflation
must thus be clear to everybody.
Conclusion
In short: "When some get incomes without work others get too
little for their work" and
"When the amount of money grows faster than production we have
inflation" to which I add:
"We have inflation when the community fails to
collect the community-created (unearned) land rent".
My contribution "to the discovery of the source of inflation has
only been of minor importance.
As a Georgist I just had the background for doing my observations
about the development in Denmark (1957-60) and in Switzerland in the
seventies, which have proved the above and that E.G. was right when he
wrote the quoted extracts from P&P, 100 years ago.
Even if he did not actually use the word of inflation, he explained
the nature of it (winners and losers in the land value rising) and the
cure of it -- L.V.T. -- I illustrate on page 10 how it will work.
With a careful study of P&P, any Georgist will come to the same
conclusion. Also to this question, his wonderful book is giving the
answers.
|