The Struggle for Freedom In South America
Felix Vitale
[Originally published in Land and Liberty,
March 1940.
Reprinted from Land and Freedom, July-August 1940]
Emigrated from Italy to Rio de la Plata, called the promised land, in
the fall of 1889; but I forget now why it was that I landed at
Montevideo instead of at Buenos Aires.
On my arrival I found a terrible industrial depression, or crisis,
which was clearly the result of recent land speculation, but which was
attributed to many secondary causes and not to the fundamental one.
In a decade I witnessed three insurrections, pompously described in
South America as revolutions, but which were nothing more than
periodical fights for power between two groups which dignified
themselves by the title of "Parties." Their only aim and
ideal was the partition of the spoils of public office. No other
problem was at issue. I am sorry to say that today there is little
improvement.
At the beginning of 1900 I had to go to New York on business. There I
met Antonio Molina, a friend of Henry George and the Spanish editor of
the Scientific American. He was born in Puerto Rico, and educated in
New York. While he helped me in my work, his hobby was to convert me
to the doctrines of his friend, and he succeeded. After three years of
unsuccessful attempts to bring to a conclusion the business in which I
was engaged, I returned to Montevideo, where with a full enthusiasm I
began my preaching, believing with the ingenuousness of a neophyte
that the truth would be easily understood and accepted in a country
where the relation between man and land is more evidently perceived
than in an old civilization where man forgets that he is a and animal.
Mine was the fallacious illusion of the visionary who believes and
hopes for a better world in a short time.
Buried in the deepest oblivion lay the memory of Rivaiavia, first
president of the Argentine Republic, and of his faithful and great
interpreter, the Uruguayan statesman Andres Lamas. One of my first
converts found in a private library the little book written by Andres
Lamas and pubished in 1881, La Obra Economics de Rivadavia
(The Economic Work of Rivadavia). The genius of Bernardino Rivaiavia
as a statesman was wonderful. He had to devise everything in a
republic which had just turned out the Spaniards, its conquerors, and
was born out of the turmoil of wars of independence. It may be that
his visits to France and Eng- and had made him acquainted with the
work of the Physiocrats or the discussions about taxation in the
English Parliament between Walpole and Sir William Wyndham.
Since his first days in public life, Rivadavia had made up his mind
on the agrarian question. In a decree dated September 1st (? 4th),
1812, providing for a survey of the lands comprised in the Province of
Buenos Aires, he declared "that the object of this proposal was
to distribute proportionately to the citizens of the country building
sites and arable land under a political system which would ensure the
establishment of population and the happiness of the many families,
victims of the cupidity of the powerful, who are living in poverty and
oppression which is shocking to reason and prejudicial to the true
interests of the state." Nothing came of this at the time, for
Rivadavia went out of office.
On May 18, 1826, Rivadavia submitted to Congress a law dealing with
the public lands, which at that time were most extensive. The first
section provided that public lands (the sale or transfer of which had
been prohibited by an earlier decree of Rivadavia) should in future be
granted in emphyteusis for a term of not less than 20 years, reckoning
from January 1st, 1827. Emphyteusis is a system of land tenure in
which the use or usufruct of the land is transferred to the holder for
a long period, but not the whole right of property. The other sections
of this law provided for a rent to be paid to the state in accordance
with a valuation to be made by a jury, and for the rent to be revised
in the same manner at intervals of ten years.
Describing his proposals, Rivadavia said in an explanatory report to
Mr. Woodbine Parish that "if the State offers to sell the lands
which are public property, it will, besides transferring them at a
price which will be more than doubled in four to six years, put in the
hands of a few dozen speculators the fortune of every foreigner, poor
or rich, who would emigrate in order to employ himself in any branch
of agriculture."
This law remained in existence for only three years from 1826 to
1829. Rivadavia was exiled and his law was abrogated and the
recollection of it sank into oblivion. Corrupted and stupid,
governments squandered the land by selling it at two or three thousand
pesos per league, instead of renting it in accordance with the
far-sighted plan of Rivadavia. Rosas, the dictator who succeeded him,
by one decree alone placed 1,500 leagues of land on sale, and by a law
of 1839, he gave at a nominal price six leagues to his generals, five
to his colonels, four to his lieutenant-colonels, two to majors, one
to captains, to officers below that rank three-quarters, and to
non-commissioned officers and men one-quarter.
Forty years ago the incubus from which these republics suffered was
the continuity of civil wars. My first statements about private
property in land fell like a bombshell. Rivadavia and his interpreter,
Andres Lamas, were hardly remembered except for the records in the
libraries of a few erudite lawyers.
A daily journal instituted a competition for the best diagnosis and
remedy for the troubles of the country, offering three prizes. My
pamphlet got the third prize. The first two were awarded to two
literary men. Their works were written in nice language and attempted
to show that wars are due to political ambition and the ease with
which peasants who are lazy and indolent and warlike by nature can be
enlisted for such fights. No economic or land question was touched on
by them. About a thousand copies of my pamphlet were distributed,
either sold or given away.
My first convert was the distinguished Uruguayan statesman, Dr.
Manuel Herrera y Reissig, who subsequently published a valuable book
entitled El Impuesto Territorial (Land Taxation); and we were greatly
helped by a business man from New Zealand, Mr. C. N. Macintosh, a
thorough single taxer with wide knowledge of all the financial and
business details which crop up in discussing the entanglements of
official political economy. I do not know how the doctrine was spread
in Buenos Aires, but I think it was due to this co-worker, who was
very influential and in contact with business men in his own affairs.
One of the recent Presidents of the Argentine Republic, Dr. Roque
Saenz Pena, originator of the law for universal suffrage, speaking in
1912, at the opening of the fifty-first Assembly of the National
Congress, said: "I consider it necessary to levy a tax which some
nations have adopted with success and the lack of which does not
indicate the distributive justice which should prevail amongst us; I
refer to the tax on the value of property which does not arise from
private effort or work but from the collective effort. All necessities
of life and all industries, as well as the labor of man that gives him
but a small return are taxed but not the enrichment which is obtained
without personal effort but by the action of the community. A
compensation is needed for such a glaring privilege. ... I think that
a desideratum of a good administration is simplification of our tax
system till we reach the establishment of one single tax imposed upon
land which is the tree upon which grows all wealth, and so we will
leave free the branches of all industries from a pruning by the state
which makes the trunk bleed twice over."
We are still in the beginnings, but new ideas about property in land
are coming to prevail. "Property in land," said the Minister
of Agriculture, "must have its limits. It will be recognized so
long as it does no harm to the progress of our country population, but
it must help the object of colonization." There is nothing
practical in this, but it is the first step, a weak step, but
nevertheless a step in a country dominated by landed gentry. About
forty-five schemes of colonization have been presented to Parliament.
Not one of them is practicable; the expense of carrying them out makes
each one impossible. The socialists are united with a group who call
themselves radicals. They have many seats in the upper and lower
house. They propose and help the passage of small reforms which, like
the lump of sugar, satisfy some working men, but leave intact all the
vested interests, nay, make them stronger. They do not interfere with
taxation. The following table will show how little the value of land
contributes to the expenditure of the nation.
[table not reproduced]
This represents only the national revenue. Each province and
municipality raises revenue by heavy taxation of small industries and
staple commodities.
I have not at my disposal complete statistics to illustrate the
distribution of land, but some illustrations will give a picture of
the situation. Very near my house one gentleman owns an estate of 22
miles in extent. Four families own between them more than 4,500 square
miles of land in the province of Buenos Aires. In the same province
there are 1,031 landowners with more than 12,500 acres each. These and
the four previously mentioned are proprietors of more than one-third
of the entire province.
There is a great fuss about latifundia (great estates) for people
realize that they need land and that it is not possible to gain access
to it. Thus the sacred right of property presents itself to the human
mind in these countries where everybody knows that the ownership is
due to violence and robbery through political tricks and corruption.
In the Province of Cordoba, the governor, Dr. R. J. Carcano, a
courageous man, defied the press and applied a tax to the big estates,
and managed it with wise judgment. The legislature of Cordoba raised
the taxes on large areas of land and reduced the taxes on small
industries, the excise, etc., so that to some extent the working man
finds work easier to get and the cost of living cheaper. It is not, of
course, the whole of our ideal. The federal taxes prevent a complete
improvement in the system. The largest item of this is the customs
duties, which are taken for granted as a necessary source of revenue.
Undoubtedly our cause seems to advance slowly, and that makes us
impatient; but no reform involving a complete revolution in an old
system can go quickly. To understand the problem of free land and free
trade the human mind must be guided by a deep democratic feeling. That
there has been some step forward in Argentina is shown by the outcry
against big landowners, by the idea that property in land must be
limited in the interests of progress, by recognition of the needs of
the agricultural laborers wandering from one Province to another in
search of work, and by the idea that land is not a kind of wealth
which should be inherited in large amounts. Politics are so corrupt,
that business, land and public offices are divided like the garments
of Christ.
In Uruguay in 1914 we had high hopes. A Bill was presented by the
Exchequer, increasing the tax on land values and exempting
improvements. It excited some enthusiasm, but not enough. Later on, a
party led by a demagogue took the matter up again, and in 1930 a daily
paper published my proposals, omitting to mention that they were mine.
But such people have no exact idea of the day-to-day evils of private
property in land, and are unable to draw the distinction between
confiscation and compensation.
In the Argentine Republic the population is generally more
conservative and reactionary than in Uruguay. But I hope that an
appeal to patriotism and the memory of Rivadavia, to whom the people
have dedicated a monument, will help to change people's minds.
Landlords have tradition and the money. We have neither. I am looking
to the English-speaking peoples. The great revolution against private
property in land was born among them; it will ripen there; we will
emulate it.
|