Economics and Social Justice in Australia
Karl Williams
[Intermediate Kit / 2002]
CONTENTS
- Introduction
- Real Environmental Stewardship
- Urban Decay or Renewal?
- Land is not Capital!
- Wealth -- and Its Misappropriation
- Tax -- a Creator and a Destroyer
- Privacy! Liberty!
- The Folly of Most Third World Air
- Land Reform -- Real and Illusory
- Capitalism and Socialism
- Henry George and Social Justice
- Taking It From Here
INTRODUCTION
"The rich grind the poor into abjectness and
then complain that they are abject. They goad them to famine, then
hang them if they steal a sheep." - Shelley (1792 - 1822)
We're going to continue to move in a spiral, rather than on a
narrow-focused reductionist path. That is, to keep you with a vision
of this big picture, we'll carry on moving around and around this
great body of Geonomics, observing a number of its many aspects. With
the wider perspective in view, we'll then start to grapple with the
details. This Intermediate Kit revisits some of the topics covered in
the Introductory Kit, but it also introduces some new subjects.
In a sense, there'll always be new aspects to discover with
Geonomics. Economics is unfortunately a dirty word these days in many
circles, which is a tragedy because it's really an awesome and endless
source of insights. Some of the many fields related to economics which
we'll visit are:
- philosophy
- prosperity
- the environment
- ethics
- politics
- technology
- history
- sociology
But - incredibly - who bothers to study economics today besides
professionals? Yet is there anything more important to understand than
economics - the great attempt to find out what makes our world go
around - except the great Journey to understand our very selves?
All the facets you gaze upon are not of equal size or luminosity, and
there's one area that clearly outshines all the rest. If this is the
only facet upon which you gaze and understand, then the energy you've
spent on Geonomics will have been amply rewarded. This facet is, in
many ways, the keystone of the arch of economics. We refer to the
mystery - some would say the madness - of unemployment.
The existence of unemployment should strike one as being
quite absurd. On the one hand there are millions of people - many
highly-skilled - wanting to work, some desperately so. And on the
other hand there is work aplenty to do - to care for the elderly, to
clean up the environment, to build better housing, to improve our
teacher-student ratio, to expand our infrastructure etc. etc. And yet,
these two things can't presently come together to satisfy each other.
So we're spiraling around, looking at all sorts of interesting
aspects, but not haphazardly. For we're deliberately preparing
ourselves to reach the top of the spiral, to find the great economic
key which will impact on just about every other aspect. For if you
solve unemployment then you unlock one of the mighty doors to
prosperity, and if you abolish the great curse of poverty then you'll
find that there are powerful and positive impacts on all the other
problems concerning the environment, social problems, war, education
and more.
Sounds mad, doesn't it? That we should claim to have an answer to
something on which politicians can never deliver, over which think
tanks continue to scratch their heads, that highly-educated academics
cannot answer. Now just visualise all these important people striding
back and forth, heads down and deep in thought over the Riddle of
Unemployment. The wonderful irony is that they're looking at the
solution! In fact, they're standing on it - it's the Earth itself!
The Earth Belongs to Everyone! And, factoring into our
economic theories the distinguishing features between land and
capital, the laws of economics are turned the right way up and now
stand out by themselves!
So, with that tantalising clue as to where we're ultimately headed in
the Advanced Kit, let's do a bit of spiraling.
"A fine is a tax for doing wrong. A tax is a fine
for doing well." - Anon.
REAL ENVIRONMENTAL STEWARDSHIP
"We shall never understand the natural
environment until we see it as a living organism. Land can be
healthy or sick, fertile or barren, rich or poor, lovingly nurtured
or bled white. Our present attitudes and laws governing the
ownership and use of land represent an abuse of the concept of
private property.... Today you can murder land for private profit.
You can leave the corpse for all to see and nobody calls the cops."
- Paul Brooks, in The Pursuit of Wilderness (1971)
Henry George laid down the principles of sane environmental policies
half a century before the world's attention began to focus on the
natural environment. To paraphrase his deep and far-reaching
environmental philosophy: "The use of Earth's scarce natural
resources should be strictly and equitably rationed by a system of
resource rentals."
NEOCLASSICAL ECONOMICS VS. GEONOMICS
Due to the current dominance of neoclassical economics, the
environment has been so recklessly plundered largely because of the
blurred distinction between private property and that of our natural
environment, the Global Commons. Put simply, private property is that
which is created by labour, whereas the Global Commons is that which
is provided by nature. They require totally different economic
treatments. We assert that the gifts of Nature should not be treated
as mere commodities, to be bought, sold, speculated upon and abused
for profiteering!
Geonomics removes taxes from wages and other private property and
increases taxes and user fees on common property. Reducing taxes on
labour increases purchasing capacity, and reducing taxes on capital
encourages efficiency. Shifting taxes on to land and natural resources
curbs speculation and private profiteering in our common property, and
clearly is a practical way of conserving and fairly sharing the Global
Commons.
GREEN TAXES AREN'T GREEN ENOUGH!
We applaud wholeheartedly green tax reforms which have started to
increase taxes and fees on:
- Emissions into the air, water and soil
- Oils and minerals
- Lands used for timber and grazing
- Oceans and freshwater resources
However, to be consistent and environmentally responsible, we
argue that green tax reforms should also increase taxes and fees in 3
other areas:
- Satellite orbital zones and aircraft flight paths
- The electromagnetic spectrum
.. these are scarce
resources that have been enormously undervalued up until now.
Almost everywhere they have been sold off to the highest cash
bidder (usually to plutocrats with political influence) instead of
governments having implemented a scheme of regularly-reviewed
resource rentals. This looting of the Global Commons by the Kerry
Packers of this world forces governments to burden us with taxes
on: · honestly-earned wages and salaries · productive
and sustainable capital and investments · sales, especially
of basic necessities But the third outstanding green tax reform is
the great current blind spot of environmental lobbyists, being a
tax on none other than:
- Land sites according to land value
In the Introductory Kit, we touched on a number of the
environmental impacts of land value taxation (LVT). The following is a
brief outline only - these kits can only hope to outline the enormous
implications of Geonomics.
THE GREAT - AND UNSEEN - GREEN TAX
LVT, as we've seen, strongly encourages land to be put to its optimum
use as an occupant must pay the full LVT whether the land is being
fully utilised or not. Land speculation, whereby a speculator or "developer"
can simply sit on a large parcel of land and wait for population and
infrastructure to build up its value, would become unprofitable. Parks
and well-used public spaces would certainly remain, but not underused
tracts of land. In other words, LVT is a recipe for the reining in of
urban sprawl.
The resultant compact, less wasteful urban landscape will have a
multitude of environmental mega-benefits. Extensive public transport
will become feasible in a smaller area, as will cycling and walking.
And we have already seen how public investment in fields such as
public transport will become affordable when increased land values are
"recycled" or recovered through LVT. Furthermore, a compact
Geonomic cityscape won't require the enormous consumption of resources
as when roads, pipelines and other infrastructure have to bypass
kilometres of unused and underused land to reach the outer limits of
the suburban sprawl. Remember, too, the environmental costs of long
and wasteful commuting journeys from distant suburbs.
Cities won't sprawl over valuable farmland, and marginal farmland
won't sprawl over what should be national parks or wilderness. With
agricultural land, there's a technical adjustment of LVT whereby the
basis of assessment is on the maximum sustainable yield, strongly
encouraging organic farming practices. In some circumstances, there's
also a good case for the requirement of what's called an Ecology
Security Deposit and/or restoration insurance from farmers.
Geonomics is firmly in agreement with those environmental groups
which call for the elimination of subsidies in areas which are
environmentally or socially harmful, unnecessary, or inequitable in
such areas as:
- resource extraction
- non-sustainable energy production
- commerce and industry
- forestry and non-sustainable agriculture
Subsidies are, essentially, negative taxes - and in
these instances (above) they are having the opposite effect to
green taxes!
MONITOR THE PLANET, NOT THE PEOPLE!
Remember too that LVT eliminates the government surveillance over
people, their activities and their assets. What LVT and other
conventional eco-taxes does do is to monitor Our One Earth as any
responsible form of stewardship should, ensuring our scarce natural
resources are not polluted, wasted, undersold or privately
misappropriated.
The bottom line of our present economic system is that not everything
which counts (our Earth) can be counted (in $ terms), and not
everything that can be counted ("progress"), counts.
Presently, it's the market which determines the "worth" of,
say, our water resources, our genetic integrity or the last remaining
habitat of an endangered species. The only moderating factor to this
is the blunt instrument of occasional government intervention, when
public outcry forces it to save what's left of our (and future
generations') Global Commons.
But there is a means of determining the worth of all of these
intangible benefits - patches of the Global Commons which confer
aesthetic, recreational, life-enhancing, spiritual,
climate-preserving, biodiversity-saving benefits.
VALUING THE INVALUABLE
To summarise an intricate but elegant principle and process, the LVT
assessment process used to determine the rent payable on residential,
industrial and agricultural land can - and must - be adapted to
relatively-untouched areas of the Global Commons facing commercial
exploitation. The assessors attempt to factor in all these less
tangible benefits of a natural resource into their valuation of its
worth to the community and to posterity. As always, these assessments
are open for public scrutiny and comment. In the end, only if a
prospective developer is prepared to pay the
full cost of utilising this resource will such extraction or
development go ahead, taking into account the proposed environmental
restoration. So a beautiful patch of rainforest might well be lost,
but only if its commercial value is extremely high (e.g. because it's
sitting on top of a huge lode of platinum).
But will local residents will lose out? Not really, because the loss
of this local amenity will, of course, be taken into account in the
next LVT assessment. And the huge resource rentals payable for this
commercial extraction will go into their rightful place - the
community coffers.
WHERE A GUESS IS BETTER THAN NONE AT ALL!
But how does anybody - professional assessor or not - possibly put a
value on something so hard-to-value as water quality or biodiversity
or recreational use? The answer is that the valuation can't be an
accounting-style series of clear calculations, but a series of value
judgments that are, in the end, quantified. It's a guess, but the best
possible guess. And the best possible guess is better than a wild
guess. And a wild guess is better than no guess at all. And no guess
at all is pretty much what we have at the moment, as the outcome of
our present neoclassical system is that such natural benefits are
often rated as next-to-worthless, and almost given away!
Chief Seattle of the Pacific Northwest indigenous tribe,
the Dwamish, tried to resist peacefully the loss of their land to
white settlers. In 1855 he is said to have written a letter
(although various versions of this letter exist) to President
Franklin Pierce saying, "How can you buy or sell the sky -
the warmth of the land? The idea is strange to us
. Every part
of this earth is sacred to us."
URBAN DECAY OR RENEWAL?
"The land question in the towns bears upon
(over-crowding). It is all very well to produce 'Housing of Working
Class' bills. They will never be effective until you tackle the
taxation of land values." - David Lloyd George, (1863 -
1945), British Prime Minister (1917 - 1922)
Want another classic example of the madness of our current
neoclassical economic system? Melbourne's Dockland Project is such, in
the sense that it took so long to happen. Look at what we had - a vast
expanse of idle land and derelict buildings sitting right next to the
central business district for decades. The Docklands area was a waste
of enormously-valuable real estate because of our failure to collect
the LVT, which would have otherwise financially obliged the owners to
put the land to its full potential or to have passed on the land
titles to those who would do so.
HOW TO ENCOURAGE SLUMS
But examples abound of needless urban decay - poorly maintained
housing, fields in urban areas with nothing on them except thistles,
outdated infrastructure, old and unused warehouses with rusted roofs
and broken windows etc. Once again, we lack LVT to get things (and
unemployed people) moving. And at present, even if you do put land to
use, you're going to be hit with taxes if you make an income or
profit, even though you're employing people and are of benefit to
society by offering your goods and services. What we
should be doing is taxing bads, not goods. Bads here is the
array of wasted resources that leads to decay, and goods are the
honest endeavours of people working in a free and a fair market. Or
put it this way: tax waste, not work. Or pay for what you take, not
what you make.
Some may object that we do have some sort of state land tax
as well as the property taxes of local governments!" However, "property"
is a woolly word which, in our current understanding, can mean land
and/or capital - two very different things. Where property taxes are
actually LVT (often termed site value rating at local government
level) they are equitable and beneficial, but the problem is they are
minuscule and misapplied in a number of ways. But where property taxes
are (more commonly) a tax on land and improvements (such as
buildings), the effect is entirely different. When the owner does, for
example, build a house or renovate a derelict building, up will go
his/her property taxes!
What society needs is a tax system which encourages land to be put to
its optimum use, and for productive labour to be free of punitive
taxation. Instead we have a system in which it is profitable for
landowners to sit and wait for their land value to appreciate, while
honest enterprise is treated as a cash cow by our tax system.
MONEY MOTIVATES!
Our conditioning has somehow led us to accept this economic and
social madness. We might travel to work and glance at an empty block
of land worth millions of dollars, yet not think twice about it. Once
we arrive at work, however, our mind-set is - curiously -very
different. Hey! - the new printing press or forklift truck has
arrived, worth a hundred thousand dollars! How long do you think
management will let this valuable piece of machinery lie idle on the
factory floor?
The same profit motive that compels someone to tear off the
shrink-wrap at once and get their new equipment working can also be
applied to the occupancy of land. To drive the point home so that your
all-taxes-are-the-same programming is forever deleted, take an
everyday example of a valuable block of land a person might occupy.
The land's value has been built up by the community as a result of the
surrounding amenities, so the occupier is rightly subject to a certain
amount of LVT. Knowing the assessed LVT, the land will put people to
work rather than weeds. Or, if the land is really valuable, it might
have a modern, efficient multi-story building on it rather than an old
single-story building or a car park.
"The burden of taxation should be so shifted as
to put the weight upon the unearned rise in the value of land
itself, rather than upon the improvements." - Theodore
Roosevelt, (1858 - 1919), US president 1901 - 1909
LAND IS NOT CAPITAL!
"Invest in land - they ain't makin' any more."
- Will Rogers, (1879 - 1935), American humorist-philosopher
This is the place to further examine the three economic factors of
production. An understanding of these economic concepts will not only
give a grounding in economic theory but will enable you to realise how
completely the so-called science of economics has been hijacked and
corrupted by neoclassical economics.
1. LAND We are putting aside, for the moment, the
philosophical thoughts about owning land to instead look at how land
behaves in purely economic terms. For economic purposes, land has a
wider meaning than that which is usually assigned to it by lay
persons. It can be defined as the available natural resources and
forces of nature. Hence land here includes flora & fauna,
rivers & oceans, air, the electromagnetic spectra and mineral
wealth. But "ordinary" land - loosely regarded as the
surface of the earth - has distinctive features, particularly urban
land with its locational value (as opposed to rural land with a
largely agricultural value).
2. LABOUR
3. CAPITAL This can be a confusing term. Capital is defined
as the product of the application of labour to land, or else can be
simply understood to be stored-up wealth or, in a sense, stored-up
labour. Capital equipment refers to the physical articles of
material wealth which have been produced, not to be immediately
consumed, but to be used to physically aid in the production of more
material wealth. This excludes pseudo-wealth: those things
described as agreements or contractual securities and obligations.
THE NEOCLASSICAL DISAPPEARING TRICK
These 3 factors of production are commonly cited in chapter 1 of
mainstream economic texts, although their definition of land is often
vague. And then - hey, presto! - in chapter 2, land has somehow
disappeared off the radar screen, and we have slipped into labour and
capital as being the only factors of production. The merging of land
into capital is the characteristic sleight of hand of neoclassical
economics. We'll return to this folly later in our critique of
capitalism and socialism.
There are
three major differences between land and capital. Again, we're
not talking about ethics, but about concrete, measurable economic
features. If you ever want a litmus test to determine whether an
economist really knows what he's talking about, just ask him, "What
are the differences in the economic behaviour of land and capital?"
If he seems to be bamboozling you with esoteric jargon, then you can
take it that the guy's a fake, for the differences are clear and quite
distinct, as you will here see.
AS SIMPLE AS 1 - 2 - 3!
1.
Land is limited in supply. Capital is not. Reread Will Rogers'
quote above - they ain't making land any more. Very important in
economic terms, and there are few examples of other things that are
limited in supply. Great works of art by dead painters is one
illustration and, just as art collectors may bid up the price for a
Monet or a van Gogh to ridiculous extremes, so too may land prices
skyrocket. Why did central Tokyo land in the late 1980's hit US$4
billion per acre? Because those requiring it couldn't make their own.
Such behaviour can never occur with capital, because capital can be
created.
This unbreakable bargaining power of land-holders within our current
economic system is one reason why Geonomists frequently attach the
word "monopolist" to land-holders. To be pedantic but also
strictly correct, we have said that land is "limited" rather
than "fixed" in supply because of the effect of the
possibility of land reclamation and multi-story buildings (not that
those possibilities gave much relief in central Tokyo or elsewhere).
2. There will always be an irreplaceable human demand for land
.. while the Law of Gravity exists, anyway. You're going to need
at least enough land on which to stand, and a bit more if you can't
sleep on your feet. Capital is different because if the seller of
capital asks too high a price from me, then I'll settle for a
different supplier, or a substitute or - failing these options -
simply do without. But I can't do without land (until the dawn of The
Age of the Jetsons). I think I can handle living without an original
Monet or van Gogh in my lounge room.
Combine the limited supply of land with a never-ending human demand,
and the monopolistic screws are turned tighter. Furthermore, take into
account that the limited supply of land is being demanded by an
ever-increasing number of planetary inhabitants, and you'll grasp why
ordinary folk are being squeezed into devoting more and more working
years to saving for their increasingly-expensive block of land. In
fact, you now know more about the factors of production - the very
basics of economics - than many of our esteemed professors of
neoclassical economics!
3. The value of land is built up by the community whereas the
value of capital is created by its makers. Land generally
appreciates over time whereas capital nearly always depreciates over
its useful economic life.
The type of land we are examining here is the all-important (because
so expensive and necessary) urban land, and the value that is
appreciating is its locational (not agricultural) value. We say that
the value of land is not generally due to any effort of the owner
for two main reasons - population and infrastructure. The growing
population will make the limited supply of land relatively more scarce
and will bid up its price. Also, a growing population accessible to
your site is generally desirable - more skills and services available,
companionship, economies of scale etc. Infrastructure, by its very
nature, provides all sorts of land-value-enhancing amenities, such as
roads, schools, power, water, hospitals, libraries etc. To return to
our point, in no way is the value of capital enhanced by others. That
of land is.
THE MONOPOLISTIC HAND AROUND THE THROAT
Let's examine further why we insist these distinctions between land
and capital are so important. Now the price of monopolised things is
unrelated to their costs of production - that of land dramatically so,
for land is not produced and its cost of production is zero. Rather,
the price extorted depends on what the buyer can afford to pay over
and above the wherewithal to survive- hence, the origin of the term "rack-renting".
Non-corrupt governments everywhere intervene to prevent monopolistic
practices, but why not do so with land, which is an essential need for
all?
We've heard the philosophical justification for sharing the Earth
equitably through LVT, but now you know the basic economic reasons.
LVT takes the annually-assessed rental value of land, created by the
community, and returns it to the community, thereby preventing
extortionate monopolistic price-gouging. And remember: collecting the
LVT enables us to slash and ultimately eliminate all taxes on labour
and capital.
"It is quite true that land monopoly is not the
only monopoly which exists, but it is by far the greatest of
monopolies - it is a perpetual monopoly, and it is the mother of all
other forms of monopoly." - Winston Churchill, (1874 -
1965)
WEALTH -- AND ITS MISAPPRIATION
"Whenever, in any country, the proprietor ceases
to be the improver, political economy has nothing to say in defense
of landed property. When the "sacredness" of property is
talked of, it should be remembered that any such sacredness does not
belong in the same degree to landed property." - John
Locke, (1632 - 1704), English philosopher
We've just seen how returns from land are, by nature, monopolistic
and, by rights, should be returned to the community. But how do we
calculate this amount?
WHO GETS THE COCONUTS?
It's perhaps best illustrated by the Robinson Crusoe scenario, where
he finds himself alone on a desert island. Rob naturally settles on
the best available land which, for argument's sake, can produce 20
coconuts per acre per month. Along comes Man Friday, who gets the
second-best land producing 18 coconuts per acre. This best,
freely-available land of Friday is called the
marginal land and, as we'll see, determines both the level of
wages and that of rent.
For how much could Rob rent out his land - 2 coconuts or 20 coconuts
per acre? Friday would only be prepared to pay 2, because he can
already get 18 from his. So here's our first definition, that of the
Law of Rent: The application of labour and capital equipment being
equal, the rent of land is determined by the difference between the
value of its produce and that of the least productive land in use.
So if Man Saturday comes along (the next day?!) and finds that the
best available land can only produce 15 coconuts per acre, Rob could
rent his land out to Saturday for 5 coconuts per acre, and Friday for
2.
What then determines the level of wages? When Friday came along and
could work land yielding 18 coconuts per acre in a month, then he
wouldn't accept wages offered by Rob for less than 18 coconuts. But
when Saturday arrived, suddenly Friday could only command 15 per
month, because Rob knows that the going rate (that applicable to
Saturday at the margin) is only 15. So here we have the Law of Wages,
which is the corollary of the law of rent: Wages are the reward
that labour can obtain on marginal land, i.e. the most productive land
available to it without paying rent.
Of course it all gets more complicated by technology, trade unions,
immigration, the existence of a pool of unemployed, personal
preferences, levels of education etc., but these strong underlying
laws always hold. But let's now tie up the factors of production. Rent
is the return to land, wages are the return to labour, and interest is
the return to capital. The law of interest can be stated thus: Interest
is the return that the use of capital equipment can obtain on marginal
land, i.e. the most productive land available to it without paying
rent.
PROGRESS AND POVERTY, SIDE BY SIDE
So here's the alarming paradox of progress marching side by side with
poverty. Those who have grabbed the best land get richer and richer
(from increasing rent) while the tenants and wage-earners get poorer
and poorer for having to accept lower and lower wages as the margin is
pushed out to less productive land). Henry George, in his classic
Progress and Poverty drove home this point, but took about 600
pages to deal with all the complications and fine details not examined
here. It's no wonder that the unmasking of this great paradox - the
title of his book - hit the 19th century world like a great
revelation. And it's no wonder that vested interests, through the
neoclassical economics that they fostered, knew they had to shut him
up. And, by successfully silencing him, it's no wonder that, despite
all efforts, increasing and ever more alarming disparities of wealth
are the norm world-wide.
But, anyway, how many coconut-basketsful of LVT should we collect?
Chuck away all those calculators, guys, for the answer is simple: Collect
the rent, the whole rent, and nothing but the rent. Assuming that
everyone has to do the same amount of work to produce their differing
yields of coconuts, when Friday came along then we'd collect 2
coconuts per acre from Rob. This would leave 18 coconuts in each of
their hands, and 2 coconuts of rent or LVT collected. When Saturday
arrived we'd collect 5 from Rob and 3 from Friday, which would leave
15 coconuts in everyone's hands and 8 coconuts of rent collected.
Result: everybody effectively shares equally in the bounty of Our One
Earth, and we have a natural, non-punitive form of revenue raising
with which to fund infrastructure.
We've already seen how speculators can presently hold on to idle
parcels of land, waiting for unearned increases in their value to
accrue to them. But here's another curse of land speculation: by
locking up productive land, it forces newcomers out to less productive
land. By "pushing back the margin", the evil of speculation
simultaneously raises rents and lowers wages. LVT makes it impossible
for speculators to enjoy unearned income.
NOT JUST COCONUTS
Let's broaden our understanding of rent by looking at some current
real-world examples. To tackle traffic congestion, governments often
limit the number of taxis by issuing licences. Because transmission
bandwidths are limited (and sometimes because of political influence),
a limited number of TV operating licences is issued. To prevent
overfishing, fishing licences are issued. History shows us that,
because of relative scarcity or changing circumstances, such licences
often become enormously valuable and are resold in the open market for
huge sums. This excess is what is meant by economic rent, and
plutocrats, big-time speculators and businesspeople dealing with such
licences or privileges are called rent-seekers.
We can now see that the term "economic rent" encompasses a
wide range of resources, and can be defined as
the excess over a competitive rate of return attributable to
owning an asset or resource whose supply is limited, at least in the
short run. Note the underlined words, for they indicate sort of
some monopoly privilege, as we have seen.
TOTALLY SELLING OUT
The problems above have exact parallels with the land problem. The
monopolistic privileges have often been sold off once and for all to
the highest cash bidder (or perhaps given away or even stolen) instead
of being auctioned and then regularly (annually?) assessed to
determine the economic rent that belongs to the community.
A limited resource is usually a gift of Nature. The windfall profits
arising from the granting of timber and mining rights are other
instances of uncollected economic rent. Otherwise, economic rent
mainly arises as the result of monopolies, duopolies, oligopolies and
cartels. The solution is either to regularly assess and collect the
economic rent, or to prevent natural monopolies (such as "public"
utilities) from falling into private hands in the first place.
"The tax on land values is
the taking by
the community, for the use of the community, of that value which is
the creation of the community" - Henry George, (1839 -1897)
TAX -- A CREATOR AND A DESTROYER
"A citizen can hardly distinguish between a tax
and a fine, except that a fine is generally lighter." -
G.K. Chesterton, (1874 - 1936), English critic, novelist and poet
Human nature is a most curious thing. Australians are taxed in
various ways for around half their average total earnings, yet few
ever seriously study the nature of these taxes and their different
effects. Perhaps they can be forgiven because of the way we tend to
use one word, tax, for a wide range of clearly different things. (If I
was a conspiracy theorist, I'd accuse neoclassical economics of
deliberately confounding the language.) A tax may be:
-
· a simple revenue-raising device · a user
fee · a fine or deterrent (perhaps with an element of
political or social ideology) · a means of redistributing
wealth (a transfer payment) · a resource rental · or
often a mix of the above.
And, just as the nature of taxes varies greatly, so too do their
effects. We've already seen some of the impacts of taxes, but here
we're going to expand our knowledge to drive home a point and counter
the effect of a lifetime of steady conditioning.
There's a simple rule of thumb which will guide us here - taxes on
land (in its wider sense of natural resources) are desirable and do
not inhibit wages or production, and taxes on labour and capital
punish both. Remember this catchy little slogan? - pay for what
you take, not what you make.
WHERE'S ROBIN HOOD WHEN YOU NEED HIM?
The history of taxation reveals that taxation has increasingly been
diverted from land to capital to today's mixture of capital and
labour. Fascinating studies have shown that the prosperity of the
average English labourer with a family of five actually peaked around
1495. This was the age of "Merrie England" when taxes were
almost entirely on land, and land prices were low. But then the
infamous enclosures of the commons accelerated, with land taxes
increasingly being replaced by taxes on capital and labour. In 1495,
the wages of the average English labourer were around 2.9 times the
cost of living, but this relatively affluent state was rapidly turned
around as taxes were shifted off land. By the mid 1600's wages were
almost down to the breadline as common land had been almost entirely
enclosed by the Crown and the "nobility".
Other examples of the destructive power of taxation abound. In the
Middle Ages, merchants and the emerging middle class were slugged.
Duties were levied on traded goods everywhere, stifling trade and
enterprise and giving rise to the inefficiencies of smuggling and
organised crime. Wealth taxes in France were based on the number of
windows in a person's house, resulting in houses being boarded up. The
same taxes were imposed in the Arab world on the number of palm trees
that a person owned - you can guess the result.
A MEDIEVAL MENTALITY
Before we modern, educated citizens start chuckling too loudly at our
forebears, we should look at our own tax system. What does the GST do
to sales (and, by implication, production and employment)? How is a
person's motivation to work affected by income taxes? What effect do
payroll taxes have on the number of people on the payroll?
But the right taxes can have constructive results. The reason why
some Geonomists advocate taxes on social undesirables such as tobacco
and alcohol is because they are not really arbitrary taxes, but an
attempt make people who choose to abuse their health pay for their
future health costs.
TAXES AIN'T JUST TAXES!
Green taxes have long been supported by Geonomists. Full resource
rentals imposed on such things as timber extraction or commercial
fishing prevent undervaluation, wastage and overexploitation. "Polluter
pays" pricing policies preserve the planet from plunderers
(sorry). In fact, the whole range of carbon taxes are forms of LVT in
the sense of being charges for use and abuse of air, water and other
natural resources.
The electromagnetic spectrum also falls within the wide definition of
land. To sell it off for good to the highest cash bidder is to set up
an exploitative and economically inefficient monopoly. The spectrum
belongs to the people who increase its value as much as they increase
that of land. Government should act as its custodian, auctioning off
for rent the various segments of the bandwidth. To prevent changing
economic circumstances or technological developments from dropping big
chunks of economic rent into the laps of bandwidth lessees, rents
should be regularly and appropriately reviewed and raised. That Kerry
Packer's broadcasting licences have appreciated by well over a billion
dollars shows the foolishness of failing to distinguish, for tax
purposes, between land and capital. And perhaps shows the political
influence of a powerful rent-seeker.
"
. the 15th century and the first quarter
of the 16th were the golden age of the English labourer, if we are
to interpret the wages which he earned by the cost of the
necessities of life. At no time were wages
so high, and at no
time was food so cheap. Attempts were constantly made to reduce
these wages by Acts of Parliament
. But these efforts were
futile
." - Professor Thorold Rogers, in "Six
Centuries of Work and Wages"
PRIVACY! LIBERTY!
"It is not enough that men should vote; it is
not enough that they should be theoretically equal before the law.
They must have liberty to avail themselves of the opportunities and
means of life; they must stand on equal terms with reference to the
bounty of nature." - Henry George, (1839 -1897)
We all-too-meekly accept being legally robbed of the fruits of labour
and capital, because we have been stooged into believing that there is
no other way to pay for responsible government expenditure. Having
established that beachhead, our governments then steadily make further
inroads into earned income as well as into other human rights. After
having been dispossessed of our share of the Global Commons, it would
seem pretty inconsequential to complain about taxation eroding
privacy, but it's worth looking into.
WADING THROUGH THE MIRE
But just how trifling is the fact that a mass of laws, too many and
complex for anyone to fully get a handle on, forces us to account for
much of our "personal" activities? Our private lives are
open to scrutiny following all sorts of disclosure. "But we have
to pay our taxes," Peabody bleats as he obediently discloses
every detail the tax system demands of his earnings, assets and
investments. "We don't need to understand all this tax
legislation," the dutiful drone on, "as we can simply employ
accountants and sometimes tax lawyers to do it for us." "It's
part of our duty as responsible citizens," Elroy explains as he
files away his complete audit trails of financial transactions &
statements required for tax purposes.
And we have to obey the law, don't we? The Tax Commissioner has
powers of investigation in some circumstances greater than the police
- in fact he is the law, with masses of legislation to support him and
his sleuths. But as he's unlikely to kick in our bedroom door in the
middle of the night, his other low-key invasions of privacy don't get
much of a mention in the media.
And now GST dumps on us the onus and cost of
collecting it. And the massive compliance costs of Business
Activity Statements alone now display all-too-clearly the time and
resources spent by taxpayers that would otherwise go into production.
BIG BENEFACTOR, NOT BIG BROTHER
While humans are being closely monitored, natural resources are not -
the inverse of Geonomics. Only recently have we been getting some laws
prohibiting or restricting certain types of pollution, but land and
other natural resources are still being treated as mere commodities
liable to being owned outright and treated as truly
private private property. But natural resources don't behave
as ordinary commodities, because many of them are scarce and some are
necessary for human existence. At least we can be thankful that
sunlight is abundant and renewable, for if it could be limited
then someone would try to bottle it up and make a fortune on it.
Geonomics does not intrude into people's lives. Unlike the current
assessors of misguided property tax, LVT assessors would never need to
inspect and assess buildings and improvements, and rarely if ever
would they need to set foot on the land itself, hence assuring
complete privacy for most people. But Geonomics would monitor the
direct usage of natural resources in order to determine the full and
fair LVT and resource rentals. Usage of this sort obviously should not
be kept private.
"We would rather die on our feet than live on
our knees." - Franklin D. Roosevelt, (1882 - 1945)
THE FOLLY OF MOST THIRD WORLD AID
"Philanthropy is commendable, but it must not
cause the philanthropist to overlook the circumstances of economic
injustice which make philanthropy necessary." - Martin
Luther King, (1929 - 1968), civil rights leader and Nobel Peace
Prize laureate
When you're confronted by those images of mournful young eyes which
gaze pleadingly at you from an emaciated body, it's pretty hard to
resist reaching for your wallet. Well, I hope that's made you sleep a
lot more contently at night, but I'm afraid the grinding poverty of
much of the Third World will grind on just the same.
THE GREAT PLANETARY CURSE
'Twas ever thus, within an economic system that, deliberately or not,
supports the mother of all monopolies - land monopoly. Landlords get
rich in their sleep because of what happens around, not on their land.
The vice-like grip of land privileges crosses all national and
cultural boundaries, and this writer has spent years tramping around
places like Iran, Ethiopia, Bangladesh, Bolivia, Yemen and Uganda, and
had this bitter fact confirmed everywhere.
Here is the type of thing I saw again and again. Landless peasants
are living on the breadline, working for their relatively wealthy
landlords. Some philanthropic organisation funds the building of a
well, so that the women don't have to spend so many hours each day
tramping to fetch it. Guess what happens to their rents when the well
is completed? With amazing certainty, rents rise in proportion to the
benefits of access to that well. It's the same deal with the provision
of roads, schools, clinics, irrigation schemes, bridges etc. Net
result: the living standards of the landless change little, but that
of the landlords are considerably enriched. Someone wasn't kidding
when he said,
"Third World aid is the giving by the poor people of rich
countries to the rich people of poor countries."
THE FEEL-GOOD FACTOR
Of course, this is not to deny outright the goodwill and even the
occasional good result of aid programs. Indisputably, emergency aid
that puts food into starving hands will always be a blessing. Also,
where there is a high percentage of land ownership, benefits obviously
accrue to more people. But to which people? Some will undoubtedly
benefit more than others, and some won't benefit at all. Furthermore,
when you factor in the political corruption of many Third World
governments, the benefits are more unevenly distributed.
THE ROOT, NOT THE FLOWER
Again, land monopoly and all its privileges would be destroyed by
LVT. Whereas landlords had been able to sit back and leave much of
their land to be idle or inefficiently used, LVT would force them
either to put it to its optimum use or to effectively stand aside to
allow others to do so. The boot would then be on the other foot, as
vast amounts of land will be thrown onto the market and labourers
would be offered a fair wage.
Nor would any landowner - small or large - benefit, in net terms,
more than another when a domestic or foreign government finances local
development . Land rendered more productive or desirable would pay
proportionally more LVT. And, of course, that LVT would not end up in
any private pocket but would be the natural source of that society's
revenue, benefiting one and all. We'll take this up a theoretical
notch in the very next module "Land Reform - Real and Illusory".
"There are a thousand hacking at the branches of
evil, to one who is striking at the root." - Henry David
Thoreau (1817 - 1862), American essayist and poet
LAND REFORM -- REAL AND ILLUSORY
"The teaching of Henry George will be the basis
of our program of reform
The (land tax) as the only means of
supporting the government is an infinitely just, reasonable and
equitably distributed tax, and on it we will found our new system.
The centuries of heavy and irregular taxation for the benefit of the
Manchus have shown China the injustice of any other system of
taxation." - Dr. Sun Yat Sen (1866 - 1925), democrat,
reformer and acknowledged "father of the Chinese republic"
In the last module we've just seen how LVT would place the benefits
of aid and development fairly and squarely in the hands of the people,
not just the landowners. "But, hang on!" comes the
objection, "There are other types of land reform besides LVT."
This, as the module title suggests, is our subject - how other types
of land reform have never delivered and never will.
VIVA LA REVOLUCIÓN!
Certainly there have been endless attempts at land reform. "Viva
la revolución!" has been the cry all through Latin
America, for instance, but the lot of the average peasant has changed
little, even with the best will in the world behind land reform.
Here's the problem. So-called land reform has always been seen as
land redistribution, based on the
same form of outright land ownership. But there are
three cogent reasons why land redistribution, as remarked above, does
not work and never will.
Firstly, to redistribute land means to divide it up. But land is so
vastly different as to make this task utterly impractical, what with
wilderness, marginal agricultural land, good agricultural land, outer
suburban land and prime real estate in the heart of the cities.
Where's Solomon to wisely divide it all up, with the added problem of
buildings and improvements that some people have built and others
haven't? Would A have to get 100 square kilometres of desert to match
B's parcel of two square metres opposite the GPO?
Secondly, even if the different values were measured at a
given moment, they would immediately begin to change, and would
continue to do so. Even if everyone might start with a parcel of land
equal in value to everyone else's, those values would at once begin to
shift. In the first year a dam is built here, a school is closed down
there, and roads are built everywhere. Appreciation and depreciation
would continue year after year, and in no time everyone's "equal"
parcels would have ceased to be such. A great way to operate a casino,
but what sort of way to run a society?
Thirdly, even if you could wave a magic wand and somehow take into
account the different and ever-changing values of land, what about new
entrants like the newborn of the next and future generations? And what
do immigrants get?
Besides the Big Three reasons above, there are two minor ones worth
mentioning.
- After the land "reform," would selling, speculating
and profiteering go on as before, or would all have to stick to
their allocated plots for the rest of their lives?
- It would require a really squeaky-clean government for the "casino"
of changing land values not to turn into a den of political
influence and corruption. Most likely, development would be skewed
towards the land of the politically empowered. Or maybe the
kleptocracy would get the tip-off to buy land where development is
going to take place.
REAL REFORM, NOT REVOLUTION
None of the problems above would exist with LVT, the implementation
of which would be far less revolutionary than that of historical land
reforms. We need land reform here in
Australia, of course - but in the Third World where poverty is
so great, matters are urgent. What good has foreign aid done over all
these years, when you look at the disparities of wealth in recipient
countries? Why do governments even today (as in Zimbabwe) still go
down the path of land reform whereby land is doled out to a handful of
government supporters?
We all know the proverb: Give a man a fish and he'll be fed for a
day, but teach a man to fish and he'll feed himself for a lifetime.
One would assume that Western governments, the World Bank and the IMF
also knew it, but they continue to hand out fish instead.
"The mere abolition of rent would not remove
injustice, since it would confer a capricious advantage upon the
occupiers of the best sites and the most fertile land. It is
necessary that there should be rent, but it should be paid to the
estate or to some body which performs public services; or, if the
total rental were more than is required for such purposes, it might
be paid into a common fund and divided equally among the population."
- Bertrand Russell (1872 - 1970), Welsh philosopher, mathematician
and author
CAPITALISM AND SOCIALISM
"Under capitalism man exploits man, under
socialism the reverse is true." - Polish proverb
There are defenders of capitalism who attack Geonomics (Georgist
economics) for being socialist. Similarly, socialists and communists
criticise Geonomics for being capitalist - in fact, Marx called Henry
George "capitalism's last ditch". Who is right?
"Capitalism" is a woolly word, meaning different things to
different people. Geonomists wouldn't criticise capitalism per se, but
rather decry "land monopoly capitalism".
WHEN TOO MUCH IS BARELY ENOUGH
Whatever is wrong with the acquisition of capital? Who would not want
to afford a roof over one's head, adequate food and clothing, some
means of transportation, a decent education, and to go travelling and
see the world? I've put this question innumerable times to
self-declared opponents of capitalism - many of them very well read -
and have never received any sort of adequate rebuttal. The response is
usually along the lines of:
"Well, some capital like that is OK, but nobody should have
too much capital". In the final analysis, "too much"
capital means any amount more than the speaker's!
The flaw here, as we see it, is that socialists do not make the vital
distinction between earned and unearned wealth when they attack the
owners of capital. Was this accumulated capital honestly earned in a
free and a fair market? Was there no monopolistic privilege? Was there
the creation of real wealth or was there merely the gaining of
speculative profits?
NO WEALTH-ENVY FROM US!
As we see it, if someone is a rich "capitalist" who has
accumulated a fortune, say, by being a great inventor, author,
sportsperson or a plain hard worker who lives frugally, then "God
bless him!" If they then want to live in a big house and drive a
big car, then "Good luck to 'em!" They've provided services
that actually benefit society in a truly free and fair market, and
they'd pay their way in the form of LVT. We need more such
capitalists!
The other capitalists are a different kettle of fish. Reaping where
you don't sow is not in the Geonomic bible, and the full retention of
the economic rent for the benefit of society would leave absolutely
nothing for the cigar-chomping, would-be robber barons. But let's not
forget the subtle forms of speculation and unearned wealth as
practiced even by well-meaning citizens by speculating in one form or
another. Unfortunately, the "quick bucks" culture is not
promoted only in investment circles. Even the nightly news promotes,
and even glorifies, speculative profits without ever questioning where
the wealth comes from.
SORRY, BUT IT'S A DUD
Socialism may well be inspired by noble ideals, but in terms of
economic policy it has been an unmitigated failure. Not that it is
necessarily undemocratic, but a command economy requires a large
bureaucracy with its attendant inefficiencies and corrupting
centralisation of power. Rent-seeking speculators have little chance
to do their stuff, true, but neither do ordinary people. There is no
economic incentive to work harder or better and, in any case, the
markets that might quickly adopt new products and processes don't
exist.
Another blunder of socialism (and especially communism) is the
failure to examine the source of property - the dictate that all
property should be socialised fails to differentiate between what is
earned and what is unearned. Again, Geonomics says that any
confiscation of privately created wealth, whether by taxation or by
private monopoly, is plain theft.
NO ROYALISTS, ARE WE!
In general, Geonomists support a
free and fair market with governments mainly stepping
in to prevent unacceptable environmental damage (which eco-taxes would
largely prevent) and unfair trading practices (particularly the
formation of monopolies and cartels). In this sense we could be called
libertarians of a sort, but often apply the distinguishing (and
pejorative!) label of royalist to conventional libertarians
who effectively condone the privileges of land monopoly capitalism.
It should be pretty clear by now that Geonomics doesn't fit on the
conventional left-right spectrum. It's the Third Way - and the only
sustainable one at that.
"George's blend of radicalism and conservatism
can puzzle one, until it is seen as a reconciliation of the two. The
system is internally consistent, but defies conventional stereotypes."
- Professor Mason Gaffney, US academic (New Palgrave Dictionary of
Economic Thought)
HENRY GEORGE AND SOCIAL JUSTICE
"Solving the land question means the solving of
all social questions
Possession of land by people who do not
use it is immoral - just like the possession of slaves." -
Leo Tolstoy, (1828 - 1910)
It was the power of the passion of George which led many of his
supporters to believe he was somehow inspired and, in fact, George
himself related an amazing inner experience he had when finishing his
classic Progress and Poverty.
THE RELIGION OF SOCIAL JUSTICE
But you don't have to be at all religious to catch on to Geonomics,
and we should stress that there's certainly no dogma in it, religious
or economic. But, while we all inevitably delve into economic theory
at one stage or another, what really puts fire into our bellies and
keeps us going in the face of so many obstacles is the whole issue of
social justice. It was this concern that fueled George's passionate
mission more than anything else, and it rubs off on many of those who
understand the fundamental economic principles he elucidated.
If you've read this far, you don't need to be told of the increasing
disparities of wealth on this planet, both in developing and so-called
developed nations. It's not the reality of social injustice that
motivates most Georgists, but rather the conviction that it's all so
unnecessary! Here's a very brief recap on why:
- Speculators can sit on large parcels of land and wait for the
community to build up its value. Land Value Taxation (LVT) would
prevent speculation, induce the land to be put to its best
possible use, and instead divert the increased land value to the
community coffers. Valuable natural resources, which often fall
into private hands, would again become part of the common wealth.
- Current taxation is largely legalised robbery. But the rich,
who often made their fortunes by misappropriating what should be
the community's economic rent, have the means to set up tax
shelters. LVT, in sharp contrast, is impossible to evade.
- At the moment, whoever is lucky (or powerful) enough to own
land earns greater and greater rent while the base earnings are
forced down as population growth pushes the point of marginal land
out further and further.
- Our tax system rewards sloth and speculation while punishing
industry, thrift, savings and honesty. Many public works,
infrastructure and beautification projects are presently
unaffordable because their value ends up in landowners' pockets
rather than being recycled back to the community through LVT.
- Land monopoly is the "mother of all monopolies".
Those without land still need it, and have to work on the terms of
those who have laid their hands on it first.
- Involuntary unemployment is totally unnecessary. There are so
many productive things that need to be done by those who presently
are prevented from doing them. Additionally, many wage earners
have their bargaining power and earning potential reduced by the
threat of unemployment.
- In the late 19th and early 20th century, a number of the most
influential American plutocrats applied their considerable
resources to stifle the work (and especially the ideas) of Henry
George, and bankrolled the installation of neoclassical economics.
In academic and professional circles today there's nothing much
conspiratorial - only ignorance and an unwillingness to admit that
their "dismal science" has consistently failed to
deliver any viable alternative. George's economic analysis has
never been seriously or scientifically challenged, let alone
undermined - and still holds as true today as it did one hundred
years ago.
- The principles of our social justice proposals are radical and
yet elegant: You don't get taxed on what you earn. What you
rightly owe to society is based on what society does for you - in
other words, on the physical and social infrastructure available
to you. Nothing more, nothing less.
- In the Third World, where land ownership is often concentrated
in the hands of a few families, things are worse. Vast tracts of
land remain unused because, without the pressure of LVT forcing
site holders to turn their sites to productive use in order to
cover the cost of the LVT, the landowning families can afford to
wait until the desperately poor work on the terms dictated to
them.
- We'll have our birthrights restored! Geonomics effectively
makes us co-owners of all the Global Commons. And land will be
effectively free of a purchase price, as land price currently is
the "capitalisation" of annual land values into private
pockets. The great burden facing all entrants to this planet -
having to save huge amounts to pay for what should be our
inheritance - will no longer exist!
As the reader may have concluded, it is not possible to stick purely
to social justice issues, keeping the economics out of it. The two
issues are inextricably linked, so that understanding the solution
to social injustice necessarily entails some more-than-basic knowledge
of economics.
THE REAL THING'S A TURN-ON!
But economics, to many people, seems so dry, money-minded and
mathematical as to be a real turn-off. Yet these same people will
often rail against injustice. Maybe it's because the problem is
obvious but the solution is hard to figure out. It is the same with a
number of environmental activists - they won't hesitate to stand in
front of a bulldozer, but much less often will they attempt to
understand the underlying economics that has led to the pillaging of
the Global Commons in the first place.
It's rather analogous to the tale of the guy who, blind drunk at
night, is looking for his keys under a lamp post. A passer-by asks, "Are
you sure you lost them here?" The drunk slurs a reply, "No -
I lost them in the alley over the road, but there's no light there."
The drunk is the environmental activist (or an ordinary citizen
angered by injustice), his keys are the solution, the area under the
street light is the easy-but-ineffectual answer (like hugging a tree
or raising taxes on the rich), but the keys really lie in the
difficult area of economics.
"Our primary social adjustment is a denial of
justice. In allowing one man to own the land on which and from which
other men must live, we have made his bondsmen in a degree which
increases as material progress goes son. It is this that turns the
blessings of material progress into a curse." - Henry
George, (1839 -1897)
TAKING IT FROM HERE ...
"The fields and the whole soil
should be
public property, that is the property of him who holds the right of
the commonwealth: and let him let them at a yearly rent to the
citizens, whether townsmen or countrymen, and with this exception
let them all be free or exempt from every kind of taxation in time
of peace." - Baruch Spinoza, (1632 - 1677), Dutch
philosopher
Economics can, after all, be free of jargon and technicalities. The
latter often cover up (or display) the ignorance of those who use such
stuff, from fools and frauds to conventional economists. Even in the
Advanced Kit, where we deal with more technical areas, we will
continue to use clear, plain English. The contents of this kit are:
- History: the Rise and Fall of Feudalism
- History: the New Slavery
- History: Henry George and the Land Value Tax
- War - Who's the Real Villain!
- Tax Evasion
- Why LVT Cannot Be Passed on to the Tenant
- When the Law is Actually Respected
- Banking and Interest · Banks and the Money Supply
- Currency Speculation and the Tobin Tax
- Boom & Bust Cycles
- Who Will Own the Land?
- Indigenous Land Rights
- Lies, Damned Lies and
.
- Local and Global Geonomics
- Free Trade or Protection?
- Unemployment - the Pieces of the Puzzle
We are not only more than happy to help you with your
understanding, but also we are not after your money! We can afford to
give the kit to those genuinely interested in a far better world, but
we're desperate for grass roots support, though - the need is great,
but apathy seems to rule and our numbers are still few. If you have
any questions about which you'd like to talk, here are some who have
offered to discuss things with you:
Melbourne:
* Karl Williams: (03) 9754 8356 or karlwilliams99@hotmail.com
* Bryan Kavanagh: (03) 9803 5607 or bryank@earthsharing.org.au
* Maurie Fabrikant: (03) 9512 4869 or fabmel@optusnet.com.au
Sydney:
* Neil Gilchrist: (02) 9630 8239 or neil@RADical.com.au
* Richard Giles: (02) 9744 8815
Brisbane:
* Phil Day: (07) 3870 3562
* David Spain: (07) 5574 0755 or davids@fan.net.au
Adelaide:
* Tony O'Brien: (08) 8297 5539 or aob@senet.com.au
Perth:
* John Massam: (08) 9343 9532 or john.massam@multiline.com.au
* Richard Hart: (09) 367 5386
Hobart:
* Leo Foley: (03) 6228 6486 or foleyl@tafe.tas.edu.au
If you are keen to journey on, here are some further steps. If you
haven't already done so, you can order complimentary copies of the
next 3 issues of our bimonthly magazine Progress. Contact our
office at 27 Hardware St., Melbourne [(03) 9670 2754], or
[prosper@vicnet.net.au]. Also, you're always welcome at our premises.
They sport a range of comfy facilities less than a block from the GPO
- hours are Monday to Friday from 10.00 a.m. to mid-afternoon (it's
best to first ring the office to ensure it will be open).
For those with Internet access, we recommend a bit of surfing around
the two websites set up by Melbourne Geonomists:
* The EarthSharing site at www.earthsharing.org.au
* The tax reform site at www.taxreform.com.au
From here, links exist to a multitude of other Australian and
overseas sites.
Don't forget that you can be listed to be notified of the next round
of our classes "Understanding Economics and Human Rights".
For those would rather get their teeth into a book at this stage, we
recommend:
- Elementary Economics by George Charles, a veteran
Melbourne Geonomist. He wrote this 90-page overview for his
classes at the University of the Third Age.
- Social Problems by Henry George. A wonderfully readable
book, more philosophical than economic.
- The Corruption of Economics by Prof. Mason Gaffney of
California and Fred Harrison of England. It's a powerful exposé
of how neoclassical economics was installed to get Georgist
economics out of the public eye. It's my personal tip - once you
read it, you will never be the same. 260 pages
"Henry George is one of the great names among
the world's social philosophers. It would require less than the
fingers of the two hands to enumerate those who, from Plato down,
rank with him.... No man, no graduate of a higher educational
institution, has a right to regard himself as educated in social
thought unless he has some firsthand acquaintance with the
theoretical contribution of this great American thinker." -
John Dewey (1859 - 1952), American philosopher and educator
Introductory
Kit *
Advanced
Kit
|