.


SCI LIBRARY

Libertarian Land Philosophy:
Man's Eternal Dilemma

Oscar B. Johannsen, Ph.D.

/center>

BOOK I: FUNDAMENTAL PRINCIPLES

Chapter 2 - Determination of Rent, Wages and Interest


To man has slowly come the knowledge that the expenditure of his energies on the treasures of the land with the aid of his remarkable tools is not merely a physical problem but is also one which involves the marketplace.

How does he unite the two fundamentals -- land and labor -- so that a torrent of wealth will pour forth in a never-ending stream? With barely any conscious thought, the solution arose through a process known as the division of labor. Men divide up the work to be performed according to their capabilities, desires and profitability.

If at all possible, men labor not only at tasks which please them but which also yield them the maximum return. So diverse are men's desires and capabilities that there are relatively few jobs which no one will attempt. Even to repair the soaring spire which graces a beautiful church, someone will step forward to assume that hazardous assignment if sufficiently high remuneration is offered.

This does not mean that tasks automatically are performed most expeditiously. Rather, there is a tendency by dividing up the work among men of different abilities and desires that man's work is performed most efficiently.

How best to use the land is much more difficult to determine than how best to employ men's energies. In primitive areas, the solution is relatively simple for it is largely predicated on physical factors. The limitless oceans are employed for fishing; the fertile valleys for agriculture; the wind-swept uplands for grazing. But, as the division of labor becomes more minute and the utilization of land more intensive, physical characteristics are hardly sufficient.

What use should be made of a piece of land, which can just as easily yield petroleum, wheat or rye? Visions of liquid gold roaring spectacularly into the firmament gives substance to the belief that drilling for petroleum would he the logical choice. But actually profitability is the determinant. If wheat yields the greatest net return, then its yellowing stalks would be seen swaying in the breeze much as a river of gold gently ripples its way across the countryside.

Physical considerations count, of course. Coal cannot be wrested from the earth where none is present, but the final arbiter is the exchange mechanism.

Exchange is the child of the division of labor. In turn, money is the perplexing offspring of exchange. And money gives birth, by means of prices, to a system of comparing the desires of men for the infinite variety of goods they produce. And prices close the circle by reacting on the very factor, which gave rise to exchange "the division of labor" for they aid in determining how to apportion the labor through wage differentials. But prices do more. They enable men to determine the best usage of land. Exchange, thus, is the mechanism by which men determine not only the goods they wish produced, but how best to expend their energies, how to allocate the land, and how to apply capital.

By what means are these abstract principles put into effect? A businessman, that is, an entrepreneur -- a particular kind of laborer -- is the kingpin. He strives for the most efficient division of labor, the optimum allocation of labor, land and capital. He does this in an attempt to produce goods at the lowest possible cost so as to make a profit.

This businessman-laborer, more often reviled than praised, is the driving talent directing the activities of others. He is the coxswain who sets the pace and guides the shell. Is a coxswain indispensable? No, without him, the oarsmen could determine the pace and direction, but not as well. Neither is the businessman absolutely essential, but without his directing skill the results would not be nearly as good.

Prices are invaluable to the businessman. They help him to determine not only the optimum coordination of land, labor and capital but also which products to produce. In the example cited, it was the difference between the prices at which petroleum, wheat and rye could be sold and the costs of the land, labor and capital involved, which determined the article produced. Since wheat netted the greatest return, that was the one chosen.

Some decry the return that the businessman receives as exploitation; that he profits from doing nothing. But a coxswain, while he does not row, is as important as any member of the crew and may mean the difference between winning and losing the race. In like fashion, the businessman is just as important as any laborer or landholder or capitalist, and may mean the difference between the success and failure of the enterprise.

Possibly, at this point a short digression on costs would not be amiss since confusion is rife as to what they actually are. Ordinarily a businessman considers his costs to be wages, rent and interest. He subtracts them from his sales to arrive at his profit but actually these items are not costs. Instead, they are shares in the product. The landlord, the capitalist and the laborers are all cooperating to produce wealth. As has been previously stated, the wealth produced is divided among the landholders, the laborers and the capitalists as rent, wages and interest.

The costs of production really are the expenditure of human energy, the depletion of land and the wearing out of capital. Costs apply to the productive phase of human activity, not the distribution portion. Costs are related to land, labor and capital, and not to rent wages and interest.

Clearly, the article, which is produced, is not a cost. The berries picked by a native are not the costs to pick the berries. The costs are the labor expended to pick them, the baskets worn out, the land depleted. Wages. Interest and rent are the result of the costs expended. And they go to the factors, which expended the costs, that is, to the laborers, the capitalists and the landholders.

It is unfortunate that the word "costs" has been applied to rent, wages and interest. By substituting this word for "share" or "division", the tendency is for the laborers, the capitalists and the landholders to look upon each other as contestants for the wealth produced rather than as cooperating parties.[1]

However, this erroneous labeling has been so deeply imbedded in men's minds that it is probably impossible to dislodge it. Therefore, the ordinary usage will be retained in this book as long as it does not result in erroneous conclusions.

Though the businessman should use better terminology and consider rent, wages and interest as shares rather than costs, nonetheless as he looks at them objectively he is able to arrive at judgments which help him to decide how best to apply land, capital and his labor and the labor of other men to the production of wealth.

Does it surprise the reader that by looking at rent, wages and interest, the businessman is able to determine what he believes is the optimum utilization of land, labor and capital? It should not. After all, production is the result of consumption. Man wishes to consume. Therefore, he produces wealth. A man wishes to drink water. Therefore, he goes to a brook and with the aid of a cup scoops some up. Because he desired to consume wealth he produced it, not the reverse.

It is true that production comes first for you cannot consume unless something is first produced, but it is what man wishes to consume that determines what he will produce. Therefore, looking at the rewards of production " rent, wages and interest" is a perfectly natural way of determining what man wishes produced and consequently how to allocate land, labor and capital.

But how is this general principle applied in the practical world? The answer is simple. Profit is the determinant. Other things being equal, the fact that one business is more profitable than another is proof that it is catering more nearly to the desires of the people than the other one is. It is producing the things which people have a greater desire to consume. It is using land, labor and capital in accordance with the people's wishes.

The fact that the determination of sales as well as the "costs" of rent, wages and interest are in terms of money, i.e., prices, has a number of important consequences. One of the most important is that businessmen usually absorb the risks of an enterprise.

As an example, an entrepreneur might have made a contract with a landlord, a capitalist and other laborers in which it was agreed that the landlord would get 30% of the product produced, the capitalist 10%, the laborers 50%, with the business receiving 10%.

Let us assume that 10,000 barrels of petroleum were produced and sold at $1 a barrel. Then the landlord would receive his 30% ($3,000); the capitalist his 10% ($l.000); the other laborers their 50% ($5,000); and the businessman his 10% ($l.000). It is obvious that they are all cooperating in producing petroleum and the amount of money divided depends on the price of the oil. While such an arrangement might be made, the following is more likely.

Instead of setting up proportions, the businessman will contract to pay a certain amount of rent, interest, and wages in money. The price at which the petroleum will sell is now his risk. If the price turns out to be 50 cents instead of $1. He suffers any loss. Since he absorbs the risk, naturally he expects and is entitled to a greater return than if he and the others all shared the risk. For that reason, he agrees to pay them amounts which would be less than if they were partners. If he was quite certain that when produced the oil would sell at $1 a barrel, he might offer to buy the shares of the others on the basis of $.90 a barrel. So, he might offer $2,700 to the landlord, $900 to the capitalist and $4,500 to the laborers. If they decided there were no better alternatives, they would accept.

If he does sell the oil for $1 a barrel, he winds up with a greater profit than if all had shared in the risk. He would receive $1,900. ($10,000 less the sum of the rent, interest and wages; ( $2,700 + $900 + $4,500= $8100)

It is at this point that many erroneously assume he is acquiring unconscionable profits. But note, the $1,900 consists of his wages of $1,000, to which he certainly is entitled, plus the extra $900 which is the compensation for the risk he assumed. The others were only too willing to let him earn this extra money in return for their not having to assume the risk of the oil selling at a low price. The additional $900 consists of $300 in rent, $100 in interest, and $500 in extra wages.

Thus, the profits of a businessman are his wages, plus possibly a combination of rent, interest and additional wages which the others cooperating with him could have earned if they had wished to assume the risks involved.

If oil sells at a very low price, the businessman discovers that he has paid the others too much for their shares. To continue to produce, he must offer them less. It they agree, then he can stay in business if he can sell the oil at a price sufficiently high so that he can give to the landlord, the capitalist and the laborers the payments agreed upon, while still leaving himself with a share which he believes is worth his while.

Each makes his determination on the basis of the alternatives to which the land, capital and labor could be put. If they find no better alternatives, they will accept the lesser shares. If they refuse, then the production of petroleum ceases at that location, and the land, labor and capital are directed to other uses.

But the most important question of all is still unanswered. How are the relative proportions which each of the cooperating agents receive determined? We have merely assumed what they would be, but have not stated by what means they were determined.

The answer is simple. Supply and demand yields the answer. While this is true enough, it explains little. How do laborers, capitalists and landlords know approximately what they can demand?

Of course a businessman utilizes the economic data available. Through calculations, he arrives at answers which guide him in his venture. But how was it determined that a piece of land in the center of town can be rented for $1,000 per square foot while another piece of the same size at the edge of town can be rented for only $75? Why are the prices not reversed?

The means by which entrepreneurs determine what rent they will offer is by making a comparison with land they are presently utilizing. For example, a businessman studies a parcel of land and decides it has greater potentialities than the land he is using. He believes that after paying wages and interest on the new site he will have left $3500 with which to pay the rent and give himself a nice return. He is presently earning $500 so he will wish to make at least that much on the new parcel. Therefore, he can offer to pay a rental charge up to $3,000 and be no worse off.

What rent would he otter? As little as possible. If he offers $2500 and no one overbids him, he would obtain the use of the land at that figure. However, we will assume someone else thought along similar lines. This competitor believes that on the new parcel he can pay as much as $3100 in rent and wind up with an income equal to that which he is presently earning. Thus, the second man raises the bid to say $2,900. While the first man could go up to $3,000, he probably would consider that it was not worthwhile as he would merely net what he is already earning, so he would drop out of the bidding. Thus, the second man would rent the site for $2,900 it no one else overbids him.

Although the comparison each man makes is with his present situation, actually the comparison is between the productivity of the land in question and the best free land available. Businessmen are not aware of it, but they are really part of a chain reaction which regresses to the best free land available, usually called the margin of production or margin of cultivation. If they were advised that the rent they are offering is dependent upon this margin, it is doubtful if they would know what you are talking about. They would insist that all they are doing is making a comparison with their present situation.

However, that the comparison is really with the margin is easy to demonstrate. If land is available from which 100,000 barrels of oil could be drawn, and if there was plenty of such land available which could be had merely for the asking, then no rent could be charged. No one will pay any rent for land, no matter how productive it is, as long as he can obtain other land which is equally as productive for nothing. It was because there was no comparable land available for the taking that the men were willing to pay rent.

The comparison between the best land and the margin could be a direct one. For example, after paying wages and interest, a businessman operating on free land might net $500. If on the best land available he believes that after paying wages and interest he will net $1500, he would be willing to rent that land at any figure up to $1000. as this would still leave him the $500 presently being earned. This would be a comparison between the best land and the poorest.

However, it probably rarely happens that such comparison is that direct. The comparison is probably the best land, A, with the second best, B. Then B with C, and so on until the poorest land "the free land " is reached.

This chain effect is an example of the fascinating harmony existing among diverse factors of our world, for it illustrates the tendency for those with the greatest ability to wind up on the land of the highest productivity. The most dynamic and resourceful man is the one who recognizes the possibilities of the best land and is able to utilize it properly so as to be able to offer the highest rent. Other men, not quite so efficient, tend to resort to land of lesser productivity, but within their capacity. Abilities tend to harmonize with the opportunities available.

For simplicity's sake, up to now we have assumed that wages were the same on the best land as on the poorest land. This is quite true if consideration is narrowed to the same amount of work done with the same skill. However, the better land requires more skill, more imagination, possibly greater speed, greater mental agility as well as superior judgment. The tendency, therefore, is for the best salesmen to wind up working on Fifth Avenue in New York. The finest opera singers appear in the great cities. The most efficient bank clerks are in the financial houses and banks in the great metropolitan areas. This is a tendency. It is not a hard and fast rule. Nonetheless, one could almost determine the type of people who will be working at a particular location by the rent it commands, and vice versa. If the people are intelligent, efficient and hardworking, it is quite likely the rent of the land on which they are laboring is high.

It appears almost as though Nature, having created us with different capacities, provided us with opportunities to match those abilities. The man with mediocre ability works on land of limited opportunity. By so doing, he probably is happy since he is not working over his head. If he attempts to work at a location which requires greater skill than he possesses, he probably will become frustrated, nervous and unhappy. The great ball player winds up in the big leagues. The fair ball player winds up in the minor leagues. Other things being equal, both will probably be happy if their abilities tend to match their opportunities.

That one has greater natural ability than another is a fact of life. Such is the way in which we are made, possibly for a good reason. While it may be human to envy these with great abilities, we should be pleased that they exist as they are so beneficial to us. The lovely aria sung by an opera star is a thrill to all who cannot sing a note. The efficient and skillful workers who aid in increasing production to the point where the prices of the goods produced drop, benefit us all in these lower prices.

An example which may give more meaning to this question of rent has to do with the difficulties of the miners in Alaska in the gold rush days of the early 20th Century. They paid no rent for panning for gold as long as there was plenty of gold-bearing land, which as far as anyone could tell was as good as any in use, and which they could obtain by merely staking it. Only when the land was all parceled out and it became obvious that some land had more gold in it than other parcels, did rent arise.

A miner who panned two ounces of gold a day on his land and who believed that for the same expenditure of effort he could obtain ten ounces on better land would be quite willing to pay rent for it. How much rent? Up to eight ounces, for that would leave him with the same quantity that he was presently earning.

Thus, he would offer some figure less than eight, say four ounces. This would leave him with six ounces, a huge improvement over his present wages. However, it would not be long before the rent would tend to rise to a figure close to eight ounces because other men would compete for that land. After all, even if seven were offered, a miner earning only two would be better off for he would now be netting three ounces.

When all the gold-bearing land in Alaska was staked out, then free land ceased to exist. But increasing numbers of men flooded into Alaska with dreams of striking it rich. But how could their dreams be realized if there was no land on which they could work? It is a sad fact that few people recognized that land represents opportunity- the opportunity to use one's talents. So when institutional or other factors prevent men from having access to land, their talents lie idle, wasting away.

For the men pouring into Alaska, the problem was a serious one. Men must eat to live. To obtain food they had to pan for gold, so they had to get land on which to work. This meant they had to make whatever deals they could with those holding the land. They would rent whatever land was up for lease. With competition intense, rents rose to the maximum. The rents tended to be the difference between whatever could be produced on the parcels leased and the level of subsistence. True, the subsistence level was rather good. For those coming to Alaska from America the standard of living was fairly high. Rather than go below the traditional level, they probably would have resorted to violence. In India, the subsistence level is very low due to generations of abysmal poverty. Therefore, if Indians had emigrated to Alaska they would have agreed to have taken much less, with the result that the rents would have been that much higher.

It is quite important to recognize that the accessibility or lack of accessibility to land affects all wages, and not merely the wages of those who directly use land. As long as there was plenty of free land in Alaska. if a man could pan two ounces of gold a day, that represented the level below which wages for other occupations would not go. Not all panned for gold. Some rendered services. For example, some men and women established laundries. Those working in the laundries demanded at least two ounces of gold daily for they could earn that much panning for gold on the free land.

Wages are determined by what a man can make on the best free land available. And when the best free land is highly productive, wages will be high in all fields. For example, inasmuch as an unskilled man could earn two ounces of gold per day working in a laundry or cleaning tables, a mechanic would naturally feel he was entitled to more. He might demand four ounces. Physicians could probably demand ten ounces.[2]

What mechanics and physicians received would depend upon the supply of and the demand for their services. In other words, the incomes of people in varying occupations are determined by the supply of and demand for people qualified to render the services desired, but the incomes are also related to the wages which can be obtained on the best free land available.

The people in the various occupations can be thought of as being in a ship which rises and fails with the tide. They are positioned in some degree of order, much like a pyramid, with common labor at the bottom of the ship and the professional men, such as physicians and executives, at the top. The relative positions will change as the demand for the people available to render particular services varies. For instance, specialists in making buggy whips may earn much greater wages than a common laborer. However, with the advent of the automobiles, such men are no longer needed. Since demand falls, so will their wages. While the drop in wages may not fall to that of the common laborers' unless there is absolutely no need for their services, it will fall below those of people with other skills, as a chauffeurs.

Wages in occupations for which there is the greatest demand and which require the greatest skill or knowledge would tend to be the highest, while in fields requiring no skill, wages would be the lowest.

But all wages would be affected by the height at which the ship floated above the bottom of the sea. If the tide was high, all wages would be high, but if low. all wages would be low. The height at which the ship would be depends upon the wages obtainable on the best free land available.

For example, if in Alaska new lodes of gold were discovered on free land from which miners could take ten ounces of gold daily, then almost immediately, all wages in the various occupations would rise relative to those ten ounces. Laundry employees would demand that sum, otherwise they would pan for gold themselves. They might settle for nine ounces because of the convenience of living in town and not having to endure a miner's hardships. All other things being equal, a common laborer's wage would tend to average about ten ounces a day.

That would affect the wages and earnings of mechanics, physicians and everyone else. A mechanic would now want more than four ounces. Since his wage rate had been twice that of an unskilled laborers, he probably would seek twice the new rate, or 20 ounces of gold. Whether he received it would depend upon the demand for and supply of mechanics. How much he would receive cannot be stated, but it would certainly be more than ten ounces. Even if he were willing to work as a mechanic at the common laborer's rate of ten ounces, his wages would still have risen by six ounces. Thus, without his having done anything differently, his wages would automatically have risen because the best free lard available had a productivity which was greater than before. And the physician could now demand much more than the ten ounces he had been receiving previously. Possibly he would get thirty or forty ounces depending upon the demand for and the supply of doctors.

The same relationship holds true in reverse. As more of the free land is preempted so that the best free land available is of lower and lower productivity, wages will drop lower and lower. Now, the mechanics and the physicians, although they had not done anything to warrant a decrease in their incomes, nonetheless theirs would drop also when the common labor rate dropped. People simply couldn't pay the higher rates. It might be said that the ship had dropped with the tide, so all were at a much lower level in relation to the bottom of the sea than before. Within the ship, the relative positions might be about the same, with the executives on the top and the unskilled on the bottom, but the position of all with reference to the bottom of the sea would now be much lower .

Unfortunately, most people are unaware that their wages are tied to what men can make on the best free land available. They do not see that the ship is rising or falling with the tide. All they are acutely conscious of is what is occurring within the ship. It might be envisioned as one completely enclosed with only a few portholes. The people are all so busy scrambling and vying with one another to raise their relative position that they never bother to glance out the portholes to note that their height with respect to the bottom of the sea is determined more by the rise and fall of the sea than with their jockeying for position within the ship. Some who do glance at the sea shrug their shoulders and say there is nothing they can do about its level, so why think about it The net effect is a mad scramble to rise within the ship. But this usually can only be accomplished at the expense of someone else. The relatively minor increase in height which might be attained is of little significance when compared with what could be attained if the tide of wealth continually rose.

A synoptic view of a developing country indicates quite clearly that the tendency is for rent to go up as a proportion and wages to decline. As the country grows, the production pie increases in size. Therefore, rent and wages - the two grand divisions of the wealth produced - increase in quantity. However, the proportions tend to change at the expense of wages. Whereas in the early stages of development rent might have taken 1/10th of the pie and wages 9/10ths, later rent might be 3/l0ths and wages 7/l0ths.

Matters are not quite as simple as the above might indicate for as a country expands, complications arise. The newer free land may be more productive than the older land. Thus wages would rise because of the greater production on the free land. Wages might rise not only as a quantity but as a proportion. However, as the nation grows until all the land is enclosed, wages would tend to drop to the subsistence level with rent soaring as a quantity. Possibly at this point, the relative proportions would tend to stabilize. Wages would probably tend to constitute the greater proportion of the annual production for otherwise production would cease, but the proportion would tend to be much less than in the early stages of a nation's growth.

Inventions and more efficient managerial methods add to the complications which becloud what is happening. These factors increase the productivity of some or all of the land. Inventions cause some land to become tremendously productive, but indirectly may cause other land to become less so. The internal combustion engine resulted in oil-bearing land becoming highly productive. At the same time, it probably caused land which was for the raising of horses to cease being used, dropping such land's productivity to zero. There simply was no need for such land as the horse was displaced by the automobile.

Inventions, education, discoveries and managerial techniques may be likened to newly created rapids which tumble and roar their way into the ocean of wealth overwhelming the older, more placid rivers of wealth. The net effect is to help raise the ship somewhat.

Some gazing out of the portholes note that the ocean is now higher and jump to the conclusion that what is necessary for raising the ship is to have ever greater rivers of education, inventions and discoveries. Such help, unquestionably. However, by concentrating on these rivers, the man made institutional obstructions which tend to prevent the level of the ocean of wealth from rising tend to be ignored. Were these obstacles removed, not only would the level rise, but more dynamic rivers of education and invention would spring forth to reinforce the rise.

Most people are puzzled why wages tend to be higher in new countries than in old ones. It is because as land is cheap most men find it fairly easy to work for themselves. Therefore, they will not work for anyone else for less than they can earn working for themselves.

Wages are determined by what men can make working on the best free land available as was demonstrated in the example of the gold miners. In America wages are still much higher than in older countries for the land is still relatively cheap. No doubt, this is surprising to the reader since some of the most valuable land in the world is in New York City. Yet relative to the area and productivity of our nation, land, on the average, in America is cheaper than land in most other countries. This is partly due to the fact that the subsistence level is higher. Inasmuch as rent is the difference between the productivity of the land in question and the best free land available, since for all practical purposes there is no more free land in America, rent becomes the difference between the productivity of land and the subsistence level. In America, if a piece of land will yield $100 in production a week, and if our level of subsistence is say, $70 a week, then the rent would tend to be $30. In England, as their subsistence level is lower than ours, say $60, the rent for the same kind of land would tend to be $40. The land, then, in England would tend to have a higher selling price as it would return a greater yield.

The subsistence level cannot be underestimated for it may determine at what point people will revolt. Since the American level is so high, we revolted at the ballot box in the early 1930's at a stage which probably amazed people in Europe or India. They would have been content to live on quite a bit less. However, as we had not yet become inured to their lower level, action was demanded. That action, unfortunately, took the form of governmental welfarism. The revolt might have become violent smashing some of the restrictions which prevented men from having access to the land, such as occurred in the American Revolution. Instead, the revolt, was channeled into welfarism administered by the State.

War sometimes causes conditions to improve in a country, but this will be true only if it happens to make it easier for men to have access to the land. If it becomes quite cheap, the economic situation will improve because wages will tend to be higher. However, as production increases, land will become more expensive and living more difficult. The great post-World War II boom in Germany was the result of two factors. First was the removal of most of the wage and price restrictions and rationing, as well as the institution of a relatively sound money. This permitted a large measure of private enterprise to flourish. Second was the fall in the price for land due to the terrible war destruction. However, now as land prices have risen, the Germans are being plagued by the same problems as the British the Americans and most of the western world.

The fundamental laws which determine rent and wages are David Ricardo's Law of Rent, and what amounts to its corollary, the Law of Wages. The preceding analysis has been an attempt to explain them in as simple terms as possible. To put them in technical terms, they are:

The Law of Rent


The rent of land is determined by the excess of its produce over that which the same application of labor can secure from the least productive land in use.

The Law of Wages


Wages depend upon the margin of production, or upon the produce which labor can obtain at the highest point of natural productiveness open to it without the payment of rent.

The Laws of Rent and Wages are complimentary. They are really two different aspects of the same thing- that is they determine the natural division of the wealth which has been produced.

To put them in a simple equation, we have:

Production minus Rent equals Wages.

P-R = W

Rent comes first, then wages. This is borne out in our every day life. In renting land we pay the rent at the first of the month, not after we have used the space. However, our wages are paid to us at the end of the week or month that is, after we have rendered our services.

Strictly speaking as rent comes from production just as does wages, rent should be paid after the wealth has been produced. However, the custom has arisen of paying rent at the beginning of the production period instead of the end. This is merely an indication of the fact that rent is subtracted from production and what is left over goes as wages.

Now, it must be emphasized that this is merely a very simplified account of what occurs. We have assumed no differences in the skills of labor. Also, the effect of inventions, education, capital, speculation in land and other factors which complicate the picture, and which are closer to reality have been deliberately left out in order that an understanding of the fundamentals might be grasped.

Probably a few everyday example will aid in acquiring a better understanding of these two simple but tremendously important natural laws -- the Law of Rent and the Law of Wages.

In the United States today, for all practical purposes there is no free land available. The land is all occupied or held under title by someone. About the only land which is freely available to all are the roads and streets, parks, deserts, tops of mountains, the oceans, rivers and some lakes. This is free land which no one can pre-empt and all can use.

Streets and roads, of course, represent a type of land which is set aside for the transportation of goods and people and is ordinarily freely available to all. Such land cannot be used for many other productive purposes. However, some salesmen do use the streets in their business. Aside from some police regulations which are ordinarily minor hindrances, the streets and roads represent a form of free land for these salesmen. They sell ice cream,, vegetables, and household goods on the streets. Many important businesses have been established in this way.

What are the wages of a salesman who canvasses from house to house? They will be whatever he can make based on his commission. If he makes $150 a week selling brushes and brooms to housewives, this is obviously the result of his own efforts -- his own production.

What would someone else have to pay that salesman to work in a store? It would have to be about $150, for by working on the streets he can make that amount, He might be willing to take a little less, say $140, since he would be saved the walking and working in all kinds of weather. But by and large, after taking into account all the factors of convenience and the type of work he likes to do. the wages anyone else would have to pay him would gravitate around $150.

If police restrictions become onerous and prevented the salesman from his canvassing, then with no free land available to him, he would be forced to accept whatever he could get from anyone needing a salesman. He could not demand something in the neighborhood of $150. He would have nothing to revert to if he did not like what was offered. His choice would be to take the best he could get or starve.

That, unfortunately, is the condition in which most of the people in the world find themselves today. Take what you can get or starve. That is because most of the land which is productive is pre-empted. There is little or no productive free land. And it is all part of a natural phenomena. As land is occupied, rent tends to go up and wages tend to decline.

That does not mean that man cannot make use of these natural laws to his own advantage, just as he makes use of other natural laws in building marvelous machines. Man does not decry the law of gravity. He uses it. The fact that the laws of rent and wages decree that rent shall go up and wages decline as man is forced to resort to land of lower productivity is nothing over which to become upset. It is something to study and analyze to determine how these laws can be used to man's advantage.

The Eternal Dilemma facing man is how to divide up the unequal opportunities of the land among the equal claimants to them with justice to all. The Laws of Rent and Wages give us a clue toward the solution of this problem.

A striking illustration of the fact that wages are determined by what can be obtained on the best free land available is exemplified by what happened to the miners in Alaska. As has been previously pointed out, when all the gold-bearing land was staked out, wages dropped to the level of subsistence at which the men there were willing to exist. It is reported, however, that after this had occurred someone discovered gold below the high water mark on the shore. Now it happened that such land could not legally be staked out for private claims. It was free to all. Naturally, all rushed to work the land. What happened to wages? They rose to what a man working on the shore could pan. Men working in laundries or on claims owned by other men demanded and received approximately what they could make panning for gold on the seashore. This lasted until the gold on the shore ran out. When this occurred, wages dropped again to the subsistence level.

Suppose a new continent arose in the Atlantic ocean comparable to what the United States was when Columbus discovered it. If this land was as freely available as much of the land of the United States was after the Revolution, many people would emigrate there. What would happen to wages in America? They would rise to a point somewhat comparable to what men could make on this new land after taking into account all the inconvenience and trouble involved in living in a new, raw country.

The discovery of America helped to alleviate conditions in Europe and probably helped to raise their basic wages slightly. With millions of people streaming to the United States to work on the free land here, wages had to rise somewhat in Europe to keep the people there. What complicated the situation, of course, was that restrictions placed by governments made it difficult, if not impossible, for some of the Europeans to leave. Thus, the free land or America was artificially prevented from having its full effect. Also, the difficulties of the long journey across the ocean, the distaste for the more primitive way of life, and the reluctance to break away from one's homeland, all helped to counter the effect of America discovery. Nonetheless, as long as the United States had no immigration barriers, it did have a significant effect. It might not be amiss at this point to consider briefly the effect of increased population. As more people entered America, they had to resort to land of lower productivity. This caused rents to rise and wages to fall. However, at the same time, the very fact that so many people came here and cooperated with one another caused an increase in productivity. This meant that the production on the margin of cultivation (the best free land available) also rose, forcing wages up. There existed two competing effects. The expansion to lands of lower productivity tended to reduce wages and increase rent. At the same time, this increase in population tended to increase production, which in turn helped to raise wages.

Inventions and improvements in the arts have had a similar effect. They tend to improve the land's productivity and raise rent and wages as a quantity because there is more of the production pie to divide. Ultimately, however, wages will fall to the subsistence level as long as all the land is pre-empted. Of course, this is a long term development.

The effect of inventions, population and many other factors act simultaneously either to increase or decrease the productivity of land. Were it possible to keep all factors constant and observe the effect of one, as inventions, it would be apparent what was happening, but this is impossible. Man's economic world is not a laboratory. Instead, it is a dynamic and confusing one which sometimes appears to operate without rhyme or reason. But, actually it is a well-ordered one, but sadly distorted by man through his lack of understanding.

Up till now little attention has been given to a highly important factor. This is speculation in land. Whenever men enter upon a virgin territory, they are perfectly conscious of the fact that with the passage of time, if the land is at all productive, it will tend to become more valuable. Therefore, they do not merely take as much land as they need. Rather they take as much as they can get and hold.

In the settlement of the United States, the pioneers staked out as much land as they possibly could even though they could never use all of it in a lifetime. Of course. the kingly rogues of Europe, with a fine disregard for the Indians gave vast tracts of land to their favorites. William Penn was given practically all of what is now Pennsylvania in payment of a debt the King of England owed his father. Lord Baltimore was given what is now Maryland. Often these grants caused serious disputes. Settlers who came here and cleared and developed the land often discovered that it might have been given to some parasite of the monarch who claimed sovereignty over that land. One of the causes of the American Revolution was the dispute between the grantees of the English king and the settlers. The grantees charged the settlers rent, and often even forced them to vacate the land. American history is studded with the violent clashes which ensued over the resolution of this problem.

Whenever people lay claim to title to a piece of land, they try to justify it. In America, either they claimed they bought it from the Indians, as in the classic case of the so-called sale of Manhattan Island for twenty-four dollars, or they claim their rights to it came from some king who had never even been in this country. These royal brigands had no more right to award land to anybody than did the man in the moon. They just arrogated the right to themselves and backed up their grants with force. Since the Indians were powerless to fight back, they were coolly ignored. The white man would have enslaved them but as the Indians were primarily nomads they were too independent. They fought until they were practically wiped out. This was one of the most shocking cases of genocide in the history of the world and it is only now that a glimmering of what occurred is coming to light.

Because the Indians could not be enslaved, the big landholders in the South encouraged the importation of Africans and made slaves of them. With such vast holdings of land, the Southerners needed many hands to work the land. If, instead, they had had smaller holdings and had worked cooperatively with one another, they might have increased their wealth by themselves. Certainly, they would not have felt the need to make slaves of fellow human beings. Hypocrisy reached an all time low when some of the same men who enslaved the colored man issued the soul-stirring Declaration of Independence declaring that all men are born with equal rights to life, liberty and the pursuit of happiness.

This land grabbing and speculation in land has other extremely deleterious effects besides those mentioned above. Not only can it cause a serious drop in production, but often results in only a relatively small portion of the better land being put into use. This forces poorer land into production much sooner than necessary which means that wages drop quite rapidly, certainly more rapidly than if land were developed as it was actually needed.

Now, it is obvious that in the United States today. wages as a quantity are, on the average, relatively high, certainly higher than 100 years ago. They are probably higher even after taking into account the depreciation in purchasing power which has been caused by the federal government's manipulation of the monetary system. However, wages as a proportion of the wealth produced are quite likely less than they were 100 years ago.[3]

In America increased population, increased cooperation, new inventions and methods of production have helped to mitigate the effect on wages as people were forced to resort to land of lower and lower productivity. It may well be that this recourse to poorer land was caused more by land speculation than by the increase in population. It is a question if the United States would be spread out the way it is today if it were not for speculation.

While wages are good in America, one would expect that with such a tremendous increase in production as exists here that wages would be excellent. The fact is that most of the people receive what might be considered only a fair wage. It is true that the standard of living is higher today as the people have more material comforts than their ancestors had. However, much of this improvement has been occasioned by mortgaging their future, as well as by a system of governmental welfarism. To help the masses, the government takes some of the rent as well as wages through taxation, which it then distributes to them by means of various welfare programs.

Since the American people are able to produce such huge amounts of wealth, it has long been a puzzle why all the people are not extremely wealthy. Only a relatively few are, and some of this handful possess such fantastic quantities of wealth that it would make even King Midas envious. There must be something terribly wrong with America's system of distributing the wealth produced, and there is. To have the government taxing production in order to distribute it is clearly an inefficient and unsound method. There must be a better method. There is.

Thus far, we have concerned ourselves with the two grand divisions of wealth - rent and wages. We have ignored capital. However, as labor invariably uses tools, it must pay interest out of its wages for the loan of the capital it uses.

It appears peculiar to learn that interest comes from wages for we have all grown up thinking otherwise. But then labor hires capital. The landholders do not, nor do the capitalists. If a farmer rents a quarter section of land from some landowner, he pays the landlord rent from what he produces. The landowner certainly does not pay any interest to the capitalist for any of the tools the farmer may use. It is the farmer who has to pay interest for the loan of any plows. reapers or trucks he borrows. And he pays this interest out of the production which is left after he has paid the rent. Just as the laborer gets his wages after he has produced, so the capitalist gets his interest after his capital has helped in the production of wealth.

To be more specific, interest comes from the increased wages which labor obtains as a result of the loan of capital. If capital did not help labor to increase its wages, labor would not use it. If a man picking beans at the rate of 20 a minute by hand, finds that after using a cutting tool he picks the same number or less, there is no point in using it. Any amount of interest which he must pay for the loan of the tool would mean that his wages were less than when he worked by hand. Therefore, it is obvious that interest must come out of the increase in wages which results from the loan of capital.

The reader may now ask, - Is there a natural law which determines what interest will be?- yes, It is the same law which is really the overriding law of Rent and Wages-- the Law of supply and Demand.

In its simplest form, the Law of Supply and Demand states that the price of an article is determined by the supply of and the demand for it, other things being equal. If the supply of the article increases, then if the amount demanded is the same, the price will tend to fall. If the amount demanded increases with the supply remaining the same, the tendency will be for the price to rise. Elaborate supply and demand schedules are often set up to illustrate this law with demand curves and supply curves drawn on graphs. The intersection point is the price at which the article is sold. However, while these graphs may help one to understand the Law of Supply and demand, they are completely fictitious. They do not depict actual points in the world of reality other than the intersection point. No one really knows the schedule of demand that exists in the minds of people. And no one actually knows what the supply of an article would be at various prices.[4]

The interest which labor will pay will depend upon the supply of and demand for capital. If there is little wealth available to be loaned as capital, the tendency will be for interest to be quite high if the demand for capital is great. If the supply is large with demand low, interest will tend to be low.

2) Now, it must be remembered that capital consists of tools. If a particular tool is produced and is the only one in existence, the capitalist could demand as interest all the increased production except for a little which would still leave the laborer more than he would have if he did not use the tool. In such a monopolistic situation, the maximum interest would be just a little less than the increase in productivity resulting from using the tool. This assumes the tool could be utilized by different laborers on different parcels of land. The higgling and haggling of the laborers for the use of this single tool would tend to make the interest a maximum, i.e., somewhat less than the complete increase in productivity.

In the absence of a patent, however, other capitalists would note the excellent return, and would build similar tools. This competition would force down the amount of interest which could be demanded. The minimum amount would be something above zero; just enough to induce capitalists to loan out tools. Therefore, in loaning capital, the tendency is for the interest paid to be almost all the increased productivity if a monopoly exists, whereas it will be a minimum of just enough to make it worthwhile to loan tools if vigorous competition exists. If there are no laws permitting a monopoly, the supply of tools would tend to increase to a point where the return from loaning out one kind of tool would be the same as for loaning out another type of tool. Capitalists would be constantly seeking those tools which would yield the maximum interest. If the return for loaning lathes is greater than for loaning reapers, more capitalists would start acquiring lathes to lend. The competition would drive interest down to a point where there would be no advantage in lending lathes over reapers.

The capitalist expects his capital to be returned in the same condition in which it was borrowed. Strictly speaking, therefore, such problems as depreciation and insurance are outside the determination of the amount of interest paid. Those problems are actually the concern of the laborer since the tool is in his possession. For the sake of simplicity, therefore, in this discussion of capital and interest, no consideration is given to depreciation and insurance. We can assume an indestructible tool which cannot be stolen.

Whereas in commercial parlance, rent and wages are reckoned in terms of amounts of money, interest is ordinarily considered as a percentage. To say the interest on capital is 5% annually is to say that for every $100 invested in a tool, $5 is the amount of interest received per year.

Inasmuch as under conditions of perfect competition and knowledge, the rate of return tends to be the same on any and all forms of capital, no doubt, the question will arise what determines whether the rate will be 10%, 5% or whatever it is.

First it might be pointed out, however, that in a society structured strictly on the concepts of justice, only wealth or services would be loaned or bartered by private individuals, with wealth being the most important. Services are usually paid for immediately or shortly after having been rendered. Even if there is some time lag between the service and the payment, no additional fee is ordinarily charged.

Since interest is the return for the loan of capital, as indicated above, it is the supply of and the demand for tools which determines the rate. But this is not to say that consumptive wealth does not have an effect on the rate. After all, ordinary wealth can be loaned just as capital can. An individual throws a party and gladly pays a fee for borrowing chairs, chinaware and cutlery. If consumptive wealth was not loaned so that all loans consisted of capital, then the interest rate would probably be lower than it is. It is a question how great or small this effect is, but it does have some.

At the present time, there does not appear to be an answer as to why the interest rate in a community is in the neighborhood of say, 5%, for many years, any more than there is to the question why the price of pins may tend to be about l0 cents for a long period of time. We are dealing with man-made as well as man-conditioned products. Capital is a man-made product just as pins are. In a society in which it is relatively easy to produce tools, interest would probably tend to be low, all other things being equal. But in one where it is difficult to produce capital, as on a frontier, the interest rate would be high. It is well-known that interest rates are higher in under-developed lands and on the frontier than in highly developed areas.

There is probably no limiting factor on the rate of interest such as exists in the case of land and labor. The rent of land is determined by the supply of and demand for land, but rent is limited by the productivity of the best free land available. Wages are also determined by the supply of and demand for labor, but wages are also limited by what laborers can earn working on the best free land available.

The most we can probably say about interest is that it is determined by the demand for and supply of capital, and the reason it fluctuates around a certain rate in a certain area is an historical one. It appears that the rate will tend to be a low one in advanced societies and higher in less developed countries. But how much higher will probably be determined by a host of factors such as the character of the people, their willingness and ability to construct a growing dynamic society, and the ease or difficulty of producing and maintaining capital.

Economists have had a field day in attempting to determine the underlying principles relating interest and capital. The results have not been too satisfactory. Possibly this is principally because the definition of capital used by most economists is so broad. For many it consists of tools, land, buildings, inventories and money. Some even include a laborer's skill and home. Essentially for most, capital appears to be something upon which a return can be obtained. Economists, therefore, are trying to determine a rate of return on something which is treated as though it were a single item when actually it consists of a host of factors which are generically different. It is hardly surprising, therefore, that none of the explanations of the determination of interest has met any universal acceptance. It appears to be much easier to refute any theory than to evolve one. Bohm-Bawerk, the noted 19th Century Austrian economist, refuted quite devastatingly most of the theories of his time, but when it came to giving his own positive theory of interest, the result was not too impressive.[5]

The economically sophisticated reader may object that the Austrian School views the market as a process. In it the actions of the entrepreneur are paramount in enabling the participants to arrive at a more satisfactory state. By noting different opportunities he revises the prices and quantities which he will buy and sell. One of the weaknesses of the market-equilibrium theory is the assumption of perfect competition and. the lack or description by which prices are changed. Possibly with increased understanding, the Austrian process theory may displace the market-equilibrium theory as more realistic.

When economists finally adopt a scientific methodology with rigorous definitions of their terms and carefully stated postulates, it may be that a solution will be derived which will meet with general acceptance.

For this writer's purpose, the correct principles which are involved in the rate of interest are interesting but not vital. What is important is whether interest is a justified return for the loan of capital. When capital is carefully defined to be merely tools, then, as will be subsequently shown, interest is justified.

If human beings are classified as capital, and the return which the slave-owner receives from exploiting them is called interest, one can hardly expect any decent human being to accept the arguments that interest is a justified return for the ownership of capital. Although, today, slaves are not considered capital, there is one particular item which is usually considered by many to be the most important form of capital, and that is land. But if land, as well as tools, is treated as though it were capital, then the return for the loan of land as well as tools is considered to be interest. But this gives rise, then, to a legitimate question as to whether interest is justified or not. For now we have two different items treated as though they were one -- the fee for the loan of land and the fee for the loan of tools. It does not follow that because it may be perfectly justifiable for a private individual to obtain a return for the loan of a man-made item, such as tools, that it is also justifiable to obtain a return for the loan of a Nature-made item, as land. In a subsequent chapter this point wilt be amplified.


Recapitulation


The rent of land is determined by the excess of its produce over that which the same application of labor can secure from the least productive land in use.

Wages depend upon the margin of production, or upon the produce which labor can obtain at the highest point of natural productiveness open to it without the payment of rent.

Interest is determined by the demand for and supply of capital, all other things being equal.

As a consequence of the laws of Rent and Wages, as a country expands, rent tends to rise as a proportion of the wealth produced while wages decline. As a quantity both rent and wages tend to rise.

(Note: Inasmuch as the principles enunciated in this chapter with regard to rent and wages are so important, a more complete explanation is contained in Addendum I which the interested reader is urged to peruse.).


NOTES


  1. It is interesting to note that those companies, which follow an enlightened policy of constantly informing their employees of the state of their enterprise and afford them a worthwhile share in the business, seem to have less labor problems. By taking the attitude that the employees are partners in the business, the results appear more satisfactory than if the feeling is that they are contestants for the profits.
  2. Those rendering personal services, as physicians and entertainers, do not receive wages since wages are that part of production which laborers receive for producing actual wealth. Landlords, capitalists and laborers give some of their production to those in the personal service field for the particular service desired. The amount which those in the service field receive, however, is related to production for the greater the wealth produced, the more wealth which can be exchanged for services. For purposes of differentiation, their income might be termed "earnings"
  3. It is difficult to prove that wages as a proportion have dropped. Accurate statistics are not available, particularly those which are over 100 years old. In addition, whatever statistics exist most likely consist of income rather than of any breakdown between rent and wages.
  4. In econometrics, which is a sophisticated discipline attempting to measure economic relationships empirically, the problem of identification particularly in demand-supply curves is a serious one. Since the data available represent only the intersection points of demand-supply curves, when one attempts to use such statistics to trace out a demand curve the question which arises is whether the curve is actually one or not. It may merely represent what is known as a mongrel equation. This is a relationship which is a mixture of the supply and demand functions.
  5. One can, of course, apply directly the formula of marginal analysis. Then, in a perfectly competitive market, based on the fundamental concept of maximizing income, Price = Marginal Cost. Thus, the price of capital (the interest rate) tends to the point where the extra gain to be obtained from using one more unit of capital is equal to the extra cost involved in using it. But, this does not answer the question why does the interest rate in a particular area fluctuates about say 5% for long periods of time. But, as indicated above, this question may he as pointless as asking why does the price for pins fluctuate say about 10 cents. (Most any modern economic textbook will give an adequate explanation of marginal analysis).
Preface and Introduction

BOOK 1

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 2

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2 * Chapter 3 * Chapter 4
Chapter 5 * Chapter 6

BOOK 3

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 4

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 5

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 6

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 7

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2 * Chapter 3

BOOK 8

Chapter 1

BOOK 9

Chapter 1 * Chapter 2

BOOK 10

Bibliography