.


SCI LIBRARY

X. How to Make Enemies in "Backward" Nations

America's Unknown Enemy: Beyond Conspiracy

Editorial Staff of the
American Institute for Economic Research



[1993]


This article is a review of anthropologist Grace E. Goodell's The Elementary Structures of Political Life: Rural Development in Pahievi Iran, New York and Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1986, 362 pages, $45, hardbound.

For the past quarter century, much of the rest of the world has indulged in an anti-American binge. In many reaches of the globe today, it is fashionable, if not obligatory, to castigate America and Americans. To those who can recall the years following World War II, when America was openly revered as a patron of democracy and economic savior of friend and foe alike, the insults hurled so casually our way today must seem especially undeserved. Often they have come from the very countries that received lavish amounts of U.S. aid.

Seldom has anti-American sentiment reached the fever pitch that it evidently has in Islamic revolutionary Iran under the Ayatollah Khomeini. To date, Iran's overt and covert anti-American activities (from ritualistic mass demonstrations, to hostage-taking, to bombings, to the mining of the Persian Gulf) have crippled two American presidencies, produced rifts in the Western alliance, and threaten to entangle American foreign policy in the Mideast even further -- if not draw us into a shooting war. It would be pointless to recount here all of Iran's bloody attempts during the past 9 years to vanquish "Great Satan" America. It also would be impossible to predict the outcome of the current U.S. naval convoy assignment in "Silkworm Alley."

Nevertheless, as Grace E. Goodell's recently published book The Elementary Structures of Political Life: Rural Development in Pahlevi Iran illustrates, there is a useful lesson (one that we have stated on many other occasions) to be drawn from our experience with Iran over the past 30 years: namely, that U.S.-sponsored centrally planned economic development projects that are channeled through existing political bureaucracies in developing nations invariably produce economic disaster rather than economic progress -- and generate animosity rather than goodwill.

Professor Goodell's book is a comparative study, based on a 4-year sojourn in Iran, of the experiences of rural peasants in the period immediately preceding that country's dramatic estrangement from the United States. She spent 2 years in a village (Rahmat Abad) during the land reform that preceded centrally planned development and 2 additional years in a "model city" (Bizhan) observing the behavior of the forced subjects of Shah Reja Pahlevi's subsequent U.S. and World Bank-sponsored development policies. Although its geographical locus is narrow, it in effect empirically tests a wide range of theories that often have been accepted uncritically by "development economists."

Goodell's study focuses on the Dez Irrigation Project (DIP) in Iran's Northern Khuzestan region during the mid-1970's, and it describes in great detail the ways that visionary "modernization" schemes irreparably disrupted usual market processes that, prior to the imposition of centrally planned development, were rapidly propelling economic growth within the Iranian peasant community.

In brief, the Dez Project adopted the World Bank's Development Model, which was inspired by the TVA and still is in use today. According to this model, huge irrigation projects, large agribusinesses, and State farms offer numerous advantages over "backward" peasant farming operations: land consolidation under single management units produces economies of scale; foreign investors are able to introduce modern agricultural technology; food urgently needed in the growing urban areas can be most efficiently produced and released to the cities by large commercial farms; and these businesses in turn gain valuable foreign exchange by their export crops, while providing nonagricultural employment through their "spinoff" industries -- such as petrochemicals and farm machinery, processing facilities for sugar, paper, cotton, etc.

The Dez Project's administrative priorities thus called for farm corporations to displace small farmers and model towns to displace the mud villages that dotted the Khuzestan landscape. As Goodell observes, the World Bank can lend only huge sums -- and these only to centralized agencies, and "It is assumed and often asserted that a given scale of benefits directly follows from the size of the investment in a project. ...[I]t is argued that incremental, locally directed production will entail too many risks, considering the enormous investment that has already been targeted deductively ... and that an investment the size of the DIP … was hardly the place for training thousands of illiterate peasants, and could hardly be left in their hands." Moreover, it is always easier for the Bank to monitor a single, compact, technocratically oriented agency with a highly paid cadre of bureaucrats than to try to fathom the "vagaries and minutiae" of the ways of "backward" peoples.

To accomplish such broad aims, the peasants were offered arbitrary payment for their lands and were transported to new housing in model towns where they were forced to pay high rents and do as the town managers demanded.

Operating on the assumption that peasants were incapable of making decisions for themselves, the Dez Project managers assumed control over virtually all aspects of peasant life in an effort to make the farming classes conform to the planners' notions of what behavior in a "modern" community ought to be. Some of their efforts to this end are laughable, as when the Shah ordered that all men had to wear "Western clothing" in the model towns. The effect in most villages was to inspire the population to pool funds to purchase a single pair of trousers and shoes to be worn whenever a villager had to deal with bureaucrats in town.

Other DIP initiatives had more dire consequences: "model" houses were designed for families of four, when the average size of village families was much larger, with the result that living conditions were either desperately overcrowded or else some family members were relegated to the ranks of the "homeless"; massive (and enormously costly) irrigation canals were built that actually reduced tillable acreage (by intersecting existing centuries-old irrigation networks); schools and health clinics were built that were never opened for use even though the model town dwellers repeatedly petitioned the bribe-seeking town managers to do so -- and even though private firms offered to run them on a for-profit basis; "traditional orchards" of fruit trees, herbal plants, and wildflowers that were shaped by centuries of Iranian peasant culture were preserved, but the peasants who developed and maintained them were barred from using them, the town managers having reserved them for special holidays when "top State officials with their families and friends, often their Teheran visitors, claimed the paradise as theirs." The State constructed many facilities -- clinics, bath houses, and high schools, but "once these fulfilled its own showy ends it did not allow their use even when others offered to staff and run them." [p.175] In effect, the Dez Project curtailed local growth and stripped the peasants of virtually all rights to decide for themselves what endeavors they would or would not pursue.

Not surprisingly, these "transformed" peasants, far from accommodating the planners' notions of behavior in "modern society," behaved in ways characteristic of people who are forced to live under total State control: they feared the State; but at the same time were mistrustful and contemptuous of State authority; they resisted wherever possible further intrusions into their personal lives and were intensely suspicious of all "outsiders"; and perhaps more significant, in the face of the demoralizing regimentation imposed by the State, they allowed long-standing ties within social groups to crumble.

With respect to this last effect, according to Goodell the greatest damage done by the DIP was in disrupting existing local political and market structures that were themselves capable of accommodating economic growth -- "modernization" if you will -- once restrictions against the free use of land and labor had been removed.


The Myth of the Witless Peasant


A major contribution of Goodell's study is in revealing the peasant farmers' enthusiastic response in Rahmat Abad to the genuine economic freedoms granted them by the land reforms that abolished the traditional privileges of the landed aristocracy. Goodell reports that rapid "unplanned" growth there had followed the granting of economic freedom in the early stages of the Shah's land reform. The villagers' behavior plainly showed that many commonly held assumptions about the "backwardness" of all peasants are sheer myth. The Khuzestanl peasants quickly adopted technological innovations, such as fertilizer, hybridized crops, and machinery (tractors, combines, etc.) that were useful to them. They vigorously sought to extend and develop new markets, even those in which they had no previous experience. By Dez Project standards, such growth was carried out on an extremely modest scale (one tractor would service an entire village; one or two trucks would carry produce to market; a single motorcycle would be shared by many families). But from Goodell's perspective this was growth on a manageable scale that effectively utilized existing resources and represented an incipient market-directed economic revolution.

Far from being bound by ancient ways, the farmers took advantage of every educational opportunity provided them. They even became their own "urban architects," abandoning their old huts for new homes on a modest scale that they subsequently planned to replace, as profits permitted, with larger, technologically more-advanced homes. They repeatedly petitioned the government for rural electrification, which would enable them to purchase and use modern appliances. In short, if permitted to make decisions for themselves, Goodell's peasants had all the earmarks of an aspiring capitalist entrepreneurial class.

Given the disruptions it occasioned in peasant life, the denouement of this story is not surprising. Shortly after the "experimental stage" in model town building was completed in 1976, the Dez Project collapsed suddenly. During the next 2 years, the agribusinesses it had fostered were declared bankrupt and the Shah and the State took them over, requesting the former peasants whose lives had been so upset to return to farm the land that had first been given them, and then taken away by the DIP.

Goodell reports that since then, the Ayatollah's revolution "finally completed the Shah's land reform for him, distributing the land even to the landless.... The revolution also broke up the State farms, surely a confirmation that these had already failed." But the irrigation system that local farmers had successfully managed on their own had already been destroyed. And since the revolution, the technical manpower needed to operate the new canal system has fled. Furthermore, fertilizer is expensive and the revolutionary government has prohibited the cultivation of cash crops lest city dwellers be deprived of the less-lucrative grains. Goodell reports that "Thus some of the formerly prosperous farmers ... have begun to lease land that the revolution gave back to the landless and smaller farmers; the former then hire the latter to work it, consolidating fields once again in the hands of a nascent post-revolution landlord class." [p. 344] In short, progressive land reform, aborted by the disastrous intrusions of visionary economic developers and the subsequent ravages of internal revolution and external war, has come full circle.

This study thus runs counter to many commonly held notions about "modernization" that have provided the theoretical basis for development economists' central plans: namely, it shows how disastrous the-bigger-the-better "overnight miracle" planning that defies markets can be and how economically creative so-called backward societies are when given the freedom to pursue their own interests. One can only hope that Goodell's stark epilogue to her Iranian story is not prologue to further misadventures elsewhere:

Northern Khuzestan showed one of the first clear public signs of the impending revolution when as early as 1976 a band of high school boys declared Dezful to be a new Islamic People's Republic. Having drawn up its manifesto, they marched on the nearby air force base. ...The villagers ... had warned me, when we listened to the Ayatollah on radio: "He will fill the city streets ... with townsmen" [i.e., those whose lives and livelihoods had been disrupted by the Shah with U.S. support -- ed.].


Dozens of other Irans are waiting to happen throughout the Third World wherever large "top down" projects have been imposed on viable cultures. Unless development economists and other international policy planners gain a better understanding of the ruinous effects of their centrally planned, State-directed "development initiatives" -- and abandon them in favor of market-directed development -- in all likelihood more of our foreign aid will end up making enemies rather than friends.

I.
CAPITALIZING ON CONSPIRACY
II.
THE SOCIOLOGY OF CONSPIRACY
III.
THE CONSPIRATORS
IV.
THE FEDERAL RESERVE CONSPIRACY
V.
WHAT DO INTERNATIONAL BANKERS WANT?
VI.
THE TRILATERALISTS' ROAD TO POWER
VII.
THE NEW WORLD ORDER I: MOLDING PUBLIC THOUGHT AND OPINION
VIII.
THE NEW WORLD ORDER II: BEYOND CONSPIRACY
IX.
THE PERSISTENT LURE OF THE FANTASTIC
X.
HOW TO MAKE ENEMIES IN BACKWARD NATIONS
XI.
LORDS OF POVERTY
XII.
THE END OF HISTORY?
XIII.
IS SOCIALISM DEAD?
XIV.
SOCIALISM IN THE BEHAVIORAL SCIENCES
XV.
A NEW EASTERN EUROPEAN ECONOMICS?
XVI.
EARTH DAY FALLOUT: THE TWO CULTURES REVISITED
XVII.
BOOMSTERS 1, DOOMSTERS 0
XVIII.
WHITHER THE NATIONAL INTEREST?
XIX.
GLOBAL WARMING AND OTHER ENVIRONMENTAL MYTHS
XX.
THE COUNTERREVOLUTION