.


SCI LIBRARY

The Essential Reform:
Land Value Taxation
In Theory and Practice

C. H. Chomley and R. L. Outhwaite


[Part 14 of 15]


THOSE who study the signs of the times can see that England has arrived at the parting of the ways, where she must choose, and choose quickly, between land values taxation and the abandonment of Free Trade. The hard winter, with its starving women and children and its battalions of unemployed, has come - the occasion so complacently looked forward to by tariff reformers as providing favourable ground for sowing broadcast the fallacious promises of Protection. They have not neglected their work, and are confidently counting upon soon reaping the harvest.

The time has gone by when men on short wages, unemployed men, and men with the fear of unemployment constantly before their eyes, will be satisfied with the assurance that England is the best of all possible worlds, that distress is more acute and widespread in Protected Germany and America than in un-Protected England, and that all they need do for salvation is to hold fast by the axiomatic truths of Free Trade. They may be assured that the plight of their country is not worse than that of others; but this is no satisfaction to hungry men. They are not in the mood for nice comparisons. They want hope of better things, and it is offered them without stint or scruple by tariff reformers with political or personal axes to grind. The Free Trader has all the best of the argument, because his case is based on truth and logic; but these advantages are nothing as compared with his disadvantage in preaching a merely negative policy. It is useless to say, " Do nothing, and all will be well," to people who feel the pinch of poverty, and are, some sullenly, some passionately, determined that something must be done.

National prejudices and hatreds fanned by the jingo press, crude aspirations towards imperial unity, the hard fact that the Chancellor must have more money to meet national obligations, all aid the tariff reformer hi undermining the traditional belief in Free Trade. The average elector is not persuaded that Free Trade is wrong; he has no very great faith in the efficacy of Protection; but it is dinned1 into his ears night and day, it appeals to his national and his fighting instincts, and, above all, it promises change which can scarcely be for the worse. So at least he thinks, and is hardly to be blamed for not realising that Protection would drag the poor into greater depths of wretchedness, and for turning away wearied from the dry-as-dust Free Trade lecturer offering him the cold comfort of immutable economic law, to listen, fascinated, if sceptical, to his mountebank rival recklessly promising work for all.

It is not, however, pure accident that land values taxation and Protection stand opposed just now as the only possible avenues which men may follow in an effort to escape from the intolerable. There is more in the simultaneous presentment of their rival claims to attention than the fact that both promise industrial change and a means of raising necessary revenue. In the first place, land values taxation is the logical complement of Free Trade. Freedom to produce is the natural complement of freedom to exchange, as Cobden clearly recognised, when, on the eve of his campaign for abolition of the Corn Laws, he urged the raising of twenty million pounds by taxation of the landlords; as Mr. Reid, Premier of New South Wales, realised in 1895 when he allied a scheme of land values taxation with the sweeping away of a Protective tariff and the introduction into his country of Free Trade as complete as that of England.

In the second place, there is reason in the often-repeated question of the artisan, "What is the use to me of cheap goods if I lose my work and have no wages to buy them with?" Protection in England would not give him the work and wages which can only come when industry is freed from the land monopoly which shackles it; but the question is unanswerable by men who cannot point the way to attack on this monopoly.

Let us take the supposititious case of an island teeming with gold, where monopoly of land and cheapness of goods, both of which have gone to considerable lengths in England, are both carried to their ultimate extreme -- monopoly to the absolute ownership of the island by one man, and cheapness to a state of affairs when goods can be obtained for almost nothing. On the island, let us suppose, when this marvel of cheapness comes to pass, there are living besides the owner one hundred people who have a foothold on the soil only by the grace of the proprietor. Since the latter can obtain from abroad all the necessaries and luxuries of life without paying anything appreciable for them, it is clear that he will have no use for the majority of the population. Half-a-dozen perhaps, to pick up the gold which pays for his imported goods, would receive starvation wages. and be charged an exorbitant rent for the cottage allotments allowed to them; half-a-dozen more might be granted the privilege of carting imported articles to the owner's house on the terms he chose to give; he might confer a boon on a number of others by employing them as personal servants. For the rest of the people he would have absolutely no use. If he were humane, he might lodge them in a poor house; if he were careless, he might allow; them to starve; if he resembled some British land- if lords, he might drive them out of the country, as; the Duke of Sutherland drove the people from their I forefathers' homes on his estates to find a home abroad or perish in the sea.

In any case, if they remained, the phenomenal richness of the island and the phenomenal cheapness of its markets would confer no advantage upon them. Having no rights in their native soil, they would be denied the freedom to produce anything to give in exchange for the cheap goods purchasable with a minimum of labour, which should be a blessing to all the inhabitants. They would go idle and starve in the midst of plenty, as thousands of people do in England to-day.

In such a community one can imagine how eagerly the tariff reformer would be listened to who promised Protection, a prohibitive tariff which would stop the cheap goods coming in from abroad and force the lord and master, the land-owner, either to go without his accustomed comforts, or permit the native labourers to make them for him. "What use," they would say, as the British labourer is saying throughout the British Islands, "are cheap goods to me if I have no work and wages wherewith to buy them ?" They would welcome the tariff which forced the land-owner to employ them and to give them a wage sufficient at least to sustain life, since dead they would be useless.

This is the scintilla of truth in Protection, the tiny glimmer of baleful light germinated by unwholesome festering conditions of monopoly. It is hesitatingly followed by unhappy people, who can see no other light as a possible guide to better things, and audaciously proclaimed a beneficent star those whom monopoly enriches.

In the circumstances we have imagined Protection might -- probably would -- mean more work, but work under the most wretched conditions conceivable. The wages of the men hitherto employed would not be raised, except perhaps sufficiently to meet the increased prices and prevent the workers from starving. Every one upon the island would remain hopelessly in the grip of the monopolist, who could raise his rents to any point he chose compatible with permitting the persons for whom he had any use to remain upon the island and live. Protection would be a sorry remedy indeed for the evils of cheapness allied with monopoly, which we have pictured, and yet it would be eagerly welcomed by the proletariat who were offered nothing else.

But how they would spurn Protection and cling to Free Trade if they were offered, as an alternative to Protection, a share in the land of the island; if its owner were forced to pay its annual rent into a fund which they shared equally with him! He could obtain the rent in no way but by employing them, not on his terms, but on theirs. He could not work the whole of the property himself in any case, but would be forced to surrender portions of it to those who would make the best use of it with their labour. Goods could not then be too cheap to please the people. The cheaper they were the more of them would they obtain in return for their wages or the produce of their labour on the land, There could be no unemployed, since all would be free to employ themselves, being equally owners of the land and able to obtain it on equal terms.

Our imaginary island, without a tariff and without land values taxation, is in the position towards which England is drifting. There never will come a time, perhaps, when the whole of the British Isles are in one man's grip, but it makes little difference to the landless tens of millions whether the number of the land monopolists is one or a few hundreds or a few thousands. They are equally denied their rights in the land God meant for them, and in the value they have given it. Their toil, made more fruitful every year by science and machinery, enables the wealthy classes to satisfy all their desires at less expenditure of the labour of the poor, and so, more and more labourers become superfluous, drift down among the unemployable, emigrate or starve.

Cheapness may never reach such a pitch that goods can be obtained for almost nothing, but it has already got to a point which makes mention of it as a blessing sound like mockery to the man who believes it is driving him from work and leaving him without a penny to buy the cheapest goods in the world. What cares the man who has worn the soles from his boots in vain search for employment if the loaf is doubled in price by any change, provided it enables him to earn a few pence to buy a crust ? Free Trade must preach a more inspiring gospel than the virtue of cheapness if it is to retain its hold upon the people, and, as a matter of fact, even Free Traders are forced in practice to admit that cheapness, under present conditions, may be sometimes rather a curse than a blessing. It would, J for instance, greatly reduce the price of many articles if all the prison labour of the country were energetically applied to their manufacture. Yet who dare advocate such a course? It would increase the wealth of the community, and increased social wealth under a sane economic system would unadulterated good; yet set prison labour effectively to work, let us say in making boots, and the cry; would go up with perfect justice that a cruel wrong; was being done in taking the bread out of honest workers' mouths. It is a monstrous thing that increase of wealth, of good things within a country, can injure its people -- but it is true. Orthodox Free Trade maintains the contrary, yet dare not act to its principles. The reason is that orthodox Free Trade states only half a truth, namely, "Freedom to exchange is necessary to social welfare." The other half of the truth is " Necessary also is freedom to produce." If freedom to produce were ensured by opening the land to labour, then freedom to exchange goods made in prison for the lowest price could injure no one. The cheaper they were the more of them would the poor obtain for their money. This, indeed, they could at present, but between conditions now and as they would be then there is difference. At present the men who make boots would be thrown out of work if millions of pairs of boots made by prison labour were put upon the market. The potential buyers of boots would not be increased, and portion of the free manufacture would cease. But if land values were taxed, so that every man could employ himself or find employment, the millions of people, who now must go without boots they need, would be able to buy the millions of pairs that issued from the prisons, and the increase of social wealth created by turning waste labour to account would be a boon to men, as every increase of wealth must necessarily be in a justly ordered world. The severest possible condemnation of our present social system is the fact that one man can injure another by making or doing useful things. We tacitly admit that he can do so when we blame manufacturers for reckless over-production; when the newspapers say that the cotton strike, which rendered men and machinery idle, was good for trade; when professional musicians find sympathy with their complaint of amateurs who sing at charity concerts. In a world which thus approves restriction upon wealth production and other social service, what chance of ultimately prevailing has Free Trade? Men will not listen to its doctrine that no restriction should be placed on wealth coming into a country, to its condemnation of the prevention of cheapness by a tariff, when they find almost universal agreement that the production of wealth within a country, and the cheapness resulting from very great production, can be beneficially restricted.

If over-production were a reality, as most Free Trade economists assert, there could be no complete1 logical answer to the Protectionist, who would check over-production by wasting labour power through the friction of a tariff. It is a dim perception of this that is turning the working classes from Free Trade, and they will never pay whole-hearted allegiance to it again until they are shown that there is no such thing as general over-production. There can be no over-production of houses, of food, of clothes, of boots, until every person is properly housed, and fed, and clothed, and shod. What we call over-production is under-consumption, arising from the social crime which gives the land, the store-house of wealth, to a few, and denies the worker the right to consume the wealth he makes for others. Human capacity for consumption is limited. The wealthiest man can only eat and drink a certain amount; even his desire to possess fine houses, clothes, pictures, motors, yachts and race-horses is liable to satiation, and as labour and machinery advance in efficiency it becomes more and more easily satiated. The result is that there is more labour power in the world than the monopolists, the lords of labour as well as of land, require to satisfy all their desires. The labourer is not permitted to satisfy his own desires by consuming the wealth he creates. Therefore he becomes superfluous and unemployed; nobody wants the fruits of the work he could do; and we have in a world of starving men and women the phenomenon to which bitter humour gives the name over-production. Free Traders must allow the people access to sources of wealth at home, if they expect the people to help them in keeping the ports open to cargoes of wealth from abroad.


Part 1 * Part 2 * Part 3 * Part 4 * Part 5
Part 6 * Part 7 * Part 8 * Part 9 * Part 10
Part 11 * Part 12 * Part 13 * Part 14 * Part 15